chapter 04

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 33

Fiscal and Procurement Processes 85

4 FISCAL AND PROCUREMENT


PROCESSES

4.1 IMPROVING SUB-NATIONAL FISCAL RESPONSIBILITY IN THE


FEDERAL CONTEXT OF INDIA

Tapas K. Sen

Second generation theories of federalism, such as those of relatively centralized revenue raising. But it also identifies
‘market-preserving’ federalism suggest that, given favourable a number of possible allocative distortions and weakening
conditions, decentralization and federalism can provide better of central fiscal capability. Instances include large-scale
incentives to governments to support market development externalities, competition in taxation and macroeconomic
and economic prosperity than centralization. The main stability concerns. The traditional model also requires inter-
preconditions are (i) a nationwide common market, (ii) governmental transfers, which could sever the link between
competition among sub-national units and (iii) no own revenues and expenditures of sub-national units—a
expectation of central bailouts on the part of the sub- combination required by the second-generation models.
national governments. The improvement occurs through Substantial intergovernmental transfers cannot be dispensed
minimization of inefficient government interventions which with in India for many reasons. One principle reason being
may drive away valuable factors of production, as well as the need to reduce the existing wide gap between the poorest
through strong links between revenues and expenditures. In and the well-off states.
the absence of bailouts, these create better incentives for An inevitable question, the answer to which can help
economic prosperity that would yield greater revenues and resolve this dilemma, is: what kind of link do we require
thus allow higher expenditures. The superior performance at the sub-national level between revenues and expenditures?
of the system of decentralization and federalism in China Would one at the margin be enough? Or, do the sub-
as compared to that in Russia, for example, is ascribed to national government expenditures have such large
essentially these factors (Jin, Qian; and Weingast, 1999; spillovers—in terms of future revenues—to other
Zhuravskaya, 2000).1 governments at the same or at a higher level that the link
Traditional theory of fiscal federalism, however, simply does not operate thereby weakening the incentives?
emphasizes benefits of decentralized expenditure decisions Qian and Roland (1998) show that under certain conditions,
due to informational advantages indicated several the existence of such transfers need not adversely affect
years ago by Hayek (1945) and popularized in the incentives, while Bird (2000) uses conventional reasoning
‘decentralization theorem’ of Oates (1972), combined with to argue that proper design and a combination of various
elements of the intergovernmental transfers can maintain
the right incentives without explicitly taking recourse to
1 China, of course, has the advantage of a favourable history. Since
technically suspect and not easily understood estimates of
a greater share of aggregate revenues of all levels of government put
together has been traditionally collected at the sub-national levels,
tax effort. However, ‘it is important to take fiscal effort into
the psychological dependence on central transfers and bailouts did account in a more general sense in designing transfers’ (Bird,
not develop in China. 2000).
86 India Infrastructure Report 2003

Based on the experience of a number of Latin American Sub-national Governments have Authority to Cut Costs,
federations, Dillinger and Webb (1999a, b) lay down eight in Particular, in Big-ticket Items Like Salaries and
conditions for reducing unsustainable sub-national deficits Wages (Number of Personnel and Wage Rates), and
in a federal system. These are outlined below along with Pensions
their applicability in India.
In a formal sense, this condition holds in India, but one
suspects that the view of state governments about the
Sub-national Governments Raise Much of Their Own
discretion to lower wage-rates in practice would be different.
Revenues
The likely argument would be that the states have no realistic
This condition is not fulfilled in India for most of the states. option but to conform to the Pay Commission awards as
Both revenue sharing and central grants significantly implemented by the central government. However, it should
supplement the revenues of the states. In some states, own be noted that many states actually had lower pay-scales as
revenues constitute a very small part of their total revenues. compared to those of the central government until the
Whether or not this is a deciding factor for the rising deficits Fourth Pay Commission awards were implemented. Pay
at the state level is, however, an open issue. parity between state and central government employees is
relatively recent.2
Transfers are Specified by Objective Formula and Not
Ad Hoc The Central Government Strictly Controls Borrowings
Ex Ante
This is largely true in India, as the bulk of the statutory
transfers, plan transfers and a significant part of the other This condition is largely fulfilled in India—at least going
transfers are formula-determined, although in the case of by the constitutional provisions—although it is not quite
the last-mentioned category the applicable formula is not clear why this is necessary for controlling unsustainable
always transparent. However, in the Indian context, it is deficits. A dependable mechanism to discipline possible
sometimes alleged that formula-driven transfers do not irresponsible borrowing by states is certainly needed, but
guarantee objectivity; the formula itself can be open to does it necessarily have to be the job of the central
manipulation by various lobbies. For example, it was alleged government? There are other views (Shah, 1998) and this
that the formulae adopted by the Tenth Finance prescription appears too centrist, as long as other mechanisms
Commission were designed to benefit a particular state. to achieve the same objective can be credibly invoked. In
Similar allegations were voiced after the first report of the any case, the major problem in India is probably the ex post
Ninth Finance Commission was out. Further, in the case failure of the central government to use the powers it already
of discretionary grants and when the benefits of the has to control borrowing by states.
individual schemes are geographically limited, the selection
of schemes supported by the central government itself can The Central Government Credibly Commits Not to
be open to lobbying; no formula will then make the overall Undertake Bailouts, Prohibiting Explicit Bailouts and
system objective. Forcing Sub-national Governments to Service their Debts
This condition is arguably the most important supply-side
Sub-national Governments’ Expenditure Responsibilities condition that is not fulfilled in India. Bailouts take many
Match the Delegation of Revenue Sources forms in India and have a long history. Not only the central
government, but also other agencies have been responsible
It is difficult to assess this condition objectively, since it is
for keeping alive this practice. In fact, there are only a few
not easy to translate functional responsibilities into
states that can boast of never having been bailed out by the
expenditure responsibilities in any obvious manner. One
central government. Often, it takes the less serious form of
way of looking at it in the Indian context would be to
advances against various kinds of transfers. As noted earlier,
examine the eventual revenue share (after tax devolution)
rescheduling of loans is fairly common. The latest in the
and the expenditure share of the sub-national governments,
history of bailouts is the discretionary central loans based
since the condition essentially relates to the relative position
on Memorandum of Understanding (MoUs) to undertake
of central and sub-national governments with respect to
an agreed programme of reforms. The worst form of bailout
such matching. The condition, interpreted this way, appears
is, of course, writing off loans entirely. Market interventions
to be roughly fulfilled in India, as the states’ shares in
expenditures and post-devolution revenue receipts were 56 2 It may be of interest to note that in some states like Punjab,
and 52 per cent in the respective totals for the centre and the salary scales were (and continue to be) higher than those in the
the states. central government.
Fiscal and Procurement Processes 87

by the central government through its agencies have also specific-purpose and general-purpose grants are required,
been used to practise disguised bailouts. Instances of higher- and within the first category, there may be need for some
than-recommended support prices for foodgrains and other matching grants also. He advocates a total pool of resources
agricultural products fall into this category. The problem for general-purpose transfer that is defined in a stable and
with bailouts is not only that it provides the wrong incentives flexible manner. On this score, the present scheme of tax
for fiscal discipline but it also allows politicization of an sharing (which accounts for the larger part of general-purpose
essentially financial matter and leaves ample scope for transfers) should meet with his approval. He also prefers
selective disbursal of favours. taking into account both need and capacity in the distribution
of general-purpose transfers, but in a simple and transparent
Regulators Force Creditors to Accept the Losses Implied fashion. This advice is not easy to implement, as there is
by Any Failure to Service Debt (Provisioning for a trade-off between simplicity and transparency. Bodies like
Sub-national Debt) the Finance Commission undoubtedly try their best to find
the golden mean, but it is an elusive goal. Even the plan
This is another important condition that is not fulfilled in grants for state plans determined through the Gadgil
India. The system of guarantees by state governments and formula—the largest element of aggregate plan grants—aim
counter-guarantees by the central government—while at providing general-purpose grants after taking into account
making it easier for the states to borrow—allows creditors both need and capacity. But the difficulty in adequately and
to avoid assessment of loans on purely commercial basis and accurately taking into account need and capacity also makes
shift the risk of default. This is true not only for financial it difficult to subscribe to his view that no specific incentive
institutions that lend to sub-national governments or public is necessary to ensure revenue effort, since it is conditional
enterprises under their control, but sometimes for commercial upon a proper design of the general-purpose transfers.
enterprises supplying goods and services to the state His advice, that no restrictions should be imposed on the
governments as well (agreements with independent power use of general-purpose grants, should normally be true by
producers like Enron are examples). Even centrally-owned definition. In some countries, the general-purpose transfers
financial enterprises like Housing and Urban Development or block grants are indeed misnomers (for example, in Sri
Corporation (HUDCO) and National Cooperative Lanka). But India is not one of these countries. On matching
Development Corporation (NCDC) have routinely grants for special purposes, variations in the matching rate
demanded state government guarantees before a loan is could depend on both the type of the expenditure and the
provided to the state-level public enterprises. This loophole capacity of the recipient. While the former type of variations
has in fact facilitated the growth of unproductive debt at are in vogue, the latter type is expected to be controversial
the state level. ‘The danger of irresistible pressure for federal and, hence, is avoided in India, although there is an economic
bailouts, and thus both types of moral hazard [relating to case to encourage the adoption of such variations too (Rao
the creditor and the borrower], is increased when the borrowers and Sen, 1996). Technical clearances which are also advocated
are sub-national governments with service provision for some of the special-purpose grants (for example, for
responsibilities that are important to the national infrastructure); are normally required in India. Bird’s final
government, such as primary schooling and police guideline relates to adequate availability of information for
protection.’ (Giugale, Korobow and Webb, 1999) all interested parties from all levels of government. Public
scrutiny is an effective tool to ensure accountability, and
The Central Bank (and Bank Regulators) is Autonomous information is its precondition. While there are sporadic
and has a Strong Anti-inflation Mandate attempts to ensure general availability of such information
The Reserve Bank of India (RBI) is reasonably autonomous (advances in information technology (IT) have helped
in terms of policy-making and is generally thought to be considerably), there is still a long way to go before the
conservative with respect to inflation. The central government governments are persuaded to become fully transparent
does have a say in matters of monetary policy, but this in both in their decision-making and in the implementation
no way rules out RBI initiatives, particularly with respect of policy decisions taken.3
to state indebtedness, for most of whom it is also a banker. Search for remedies to the problem of fiscal indiscipline
RBI also performs the role of the regulator for all financial in India has tended to focus more and more on imposition
institutions. 3 Confidentiality is often carried to ridiculous lengths in government
Bird (2000) provides some guidelines on the design of
departments in India. This obsession actually signifies the difficulties
intergovernmental transfers that would help to contain fiscal that confront any attempt to introduce transparency. The policy of
imbalances at the sub-national level in cases where such confidentiality is also convenient for the concerned parties as it
transfers are essential and significant. He believes that both prevents exposure of corruption, bias and plain inefficiency.
88 India Infrastructure Report 2003

Box 4.1.1
Colombia: Ley de Semáforos or The Traffic Light Law

Criterion: Interest Payments/ Rating Result


Operational Savings
<40% Green No restriction on debt
40%–60% Yellow Debt allowed by
Ministry of Finance only after
review of Debt-service projections
>60% Red Debt allowed only under agreement
to enforce adjustment Plan

Note: Operational Savings = current receipts–personnel costs.


Source: Dillinger and Webb (1999b).

of controls over state budgets from the centre through the inequitable. Thus, at the present juncture, there may be no
mechanism of MoUs coupled with ‘incentives’ for good option but to allow both central supervision and market test
fiscal conduct, that is, in essence, hierarchical controls. of state finances. A recent World Bank study, examining the
While there can be no questioning the need for incentives issue of soft budget constraints at the sub-national level,
to induce good fiscal behaviour and disincentives to suggests a ‘middle road’ and concludes that, ‘countries need
discourage irresponsibility, the main issue relates to the not make a choice between dysfunctional markets and blunt
desirability of hierarchical controls vis-à-vis market and self- hierarchy. Hierarchical instruments can be honed and
enforcement in fostering discipline among sub-national made to supplement market mechanisms rather than to
governments. obstruct their growing role’. Such a middle road, the study
It is now well recognized that the problem of soft budget argues, ‘belongs to the decentralization process’ and ‘market
among sub-national governments arises from the absence of discipline can grow only as a process of gradual central
a credible commitment to a hard budget constraint on the government disengagement’ (Rodden and Eskeland,
part of the higher-level governments. However, experience forthcoming). One may add that in the particular context
shows that it is impractical to ignore the economic, political of India, it may be necessary to build in adequate safeguards
and sociological spillovers of financial crises at the state level for maintaining the federal fabric in the institutional
on the centre and the national economy. At the same time, arrangements.
similar reasoning leading to expectations of bailouts, Having advocated a market-based system of state-level
undermines incentives for fiscal discipline at the state level. borrowing, one must also consider the question of a possible
In this background, a more effective way of inducing fiscal cap on their debt, particularly, market borrowing. One way
discipline among the states is, probably, to rely on the would be to have statutory fiscal responsibility, defined in
market, whereby, they are obligated to go to the market for a way that automatically caps debt at some level. This has
borrowing and bear the cost as assessed by the market the advantage that it would be voluntary on the part of the
through the process of rating. The efficiency of the markets, states and would not be construed as an attack on the state
however, depends on certain conditions which have to be autonomy. But the flip side of the same consideration would
satisfied. Primary among such conditions are the availability be that unless a state’s politicians (and bureaucrats) suddenly
of information on the finances of the states and the existence become virtuous—or the state’s electorate becomes conscious
of independent (rating) agencies that can process these enough about such problems to engender such virtuosity—
information efficiently in an intelligible manner for the voluntary fiscal responsibility may not ever come about in
market at large. some cases. Hence, it seems that some capping mechanism
Acknowledging that fiscal-policy coordination poses a is necessary.
challenge for federal systems and that Maastricht guidelines A simple, rule-based system would be the best, as it
provide a useful framework for the purpose, Shah (1998) would be easily understood and the least controversial, as
argues that they do not quite provide an answer to the long as the control was not exercised by the central
challenge of fiscal coordination in a federal system. In a government in specific cases of infringement. However,
developing country like India where the economic strength simple systems like the Colombian ‘Traffic Light Rule’ (Box
and level of development vary widely among sub-national 4.1.1) could end up providing some perverse incentives. In
units, a fully market-oriented system can be potentially that system, for example, unnecessarily widespread
Fiscal and Procurement Processes 89

Box 4.1.2
M ar ket-B
arket-B ased R
ket-Based egulation of SSub-N
Regulation ub-N ational D
ub-National ebt in M
Debt exico
Mexico

The Mexican reforms of the sub-national debt system introduced in late 1999 and fully effective from April 2000 consists of the
following six components:
• Starting with the budget for the year 2000, the federal government gave up all executive powers for discretionary transfers.
• The system of mandatos (mandates) was abolished; this system allowed the federal government to accept states acting as trustees
for debt-servicing with the participaciones (revenue-sharing) serving as collaterals. The creditors and the states were left to make their
own arrangements, including collateralization of revenue-sharing, but without any federal commitment.
• The regimen de excepción that allowed waiver of normal single-customer exposure limits for banks in the cases of lending to
sub-national governments was removed.
• A link was established between capital risk weighting (between 20 and 115 per cent) of bank loans and the concerned state
government’s credit rating by two reputed agencies.
• Sub-national loans may be registered with the federal government, conditional upon full updated disclosure of its debt-related
statistics. Registration is not compulsory, but all unregistered loans are automatically risk-weighted at 150 per cent.
• High risk-weighted loans mean very high interest rates on loans from banks, and are effectively priced out. Federally-owned
development banks are not allowed to lend to states and municipalities when the loan is not registered or the capital risk weighting
is 100 per cent or above in the normal course. Such loans are allowed by federal development banks only when the loan package
contains a technical assistance component funded by an international development finance institution.
Source: Giugale, Korobow and Webb (1999).

government intervention with high levels of subsidies would importance at the cost of sub-national budgetary needs
be encouraged, since the current receipts will rise with (Grewal, 2000).
governmental expansion, but as long as personnel costs did What is suggested here for consideration is a system that
not rise proportionately, it would qualify the state for higher would have the following features:
borrowings. Also, a rule-based system of controlling sub- • substitution of plan loans by market borrowing;
national debt is rarely sufficient by itself. After all, the • scaling down of Gadgil formula assistance by 50 per
growth of contingent liabilities and some other forms of cent, consisting entirely of grants (for non-special category
debt not under central control probably represent a successful states; the current system for special category states may
strategy adopted by states to borrow and spend, while continue unchanged);
avoiding the constitutional constraints on their debt. Even • market determination of interest rates through a
in an industrialized country like Germany, where borrowings suitable mechanism operated by RBI, possibly through
are supposed to be restricted to the amount of capital auction of the state-government bonds. The state
expenditures only, ‘all levels of government are quite governments will be free to get their bonds credit-rated by
innovative in developing procedures to circumvent debt recognized agencies that RBI approves;
restrictions. These practices include reclassifying current • a disqualifying limit (say 25 per cent) set by the ratio
expenditures as capital (investment) expenditures, setting of interest payments to revenue expenditure of the concerned
up entities whose operations are kept off-budget, and using state, beyond which RBI will not undertake to market the
innovative debt instruments such as private–public bonds;
partnership in running and financing infrastructure projects’. • negotiated loans of public enterprises, statutory boards,
(Seitz, 2000). etc. from financial institutions will not be provided with
The new Mexican system (Box 4.1.2) is, on the other any form of government guarantee. Any state not observing
hand, too complicated and involves too many parties besides this rule will not have the benefit of marketing of its bonds
the state government (credit rating agencies, the federal by RBI;
government, international agencies and actual lenders), • a discretionary limit of another 5 per cent of the same
although the manner of ensuring full disclosure is worth ratio, provided RBI is given full information on the state’s
emulating. Lessons from the evolution of the Australian liabilities and a credible plan for better fiscal management; and
Loan Council system show that any complicated and non- • additional special ad hoc loans from the central
interactive system is not likely to work for a prolonged government, the quantum and the terms specified only on
length of time. An ideal system should not be based on the recommendation of at least 75 per cent of the members
externally-given, inflexible limits, particularly when of the National Development Council (NDC). NDC would
macroeconomic parameters are given paramount decide special cases on the basis of an assessment by the
90 India Infrastructure Report 2003

Planning Commission and on a presentation of their case possible improvements in the estimation of normative
by the representative of the concerned state. The central revenues and expenditures for the purpose of statutory
government will have a veto power, but no loans can be transfers and some marginal improvements in the system of
given to states on its own by the central government. plan assistance, the incentives in the present system of
Some of the elements of the scheme have been proposed current transfers are considerably better than those obtained
elsewhere (Chelliah, 1998). Such a system will address the in the past; further improvements must weigh the trade-off
basic concerns of macroeconomic imbalances, state autonomy with simplicity as also with political and administrative
and special considerations, without unduly loosening the feasibility. Further incentives for optimal fiscal behaviour
market regulation of sub-national borrowing. Obviously, must also come from the electorate, but the system must
this kind of supply-side measures need to be coupled with be amended to allow complete transparency for the electorate
measures on the demand side, but one feels that excepting to discipline errant governments.

Box 4.1.3
Fiscal Transpar ency and IIndia
ransparency ndia

Realizing the significance of information asymmetry on the working of markets, and on the behaviour of global capital markets
in particular, the International Monetory Fund (IMF) has evolved and adopted a ‘Code of Good Practices on Fiscal Transparency’
in 1998. India is a member of the interim committee of the board of governors, which adopted the code. Information asymmetry,
caused by lack of fiscal transparency, leads to financial crises. Fiscal transparency is a prerequisite for the evaluation of the fiscal
soundness or the fiscal efficiency of governments and their parastatals by the markets as well as by the public especially in societies
where financial markets are expected to play an allocative role. The code on fiscal transparency is just one of various codes and standards
suggested by IMF, viz., the International Financial Standards and Codes. The four principles from which the detailed guidelines
that constitute the code were derived are:
• Clarity of roles and responsibilities within the government and between the government and the rest of the economy
• Public availability of information on fiscal outcomes
• Open and transparent budget preparation, execution, and reporting
• Assurance of integrity, including those relating to the quality of fiscal data and the need for independent scrutiny of fiscal
information

ADVISORY GROUP ON FISCAL TRANSPARENCY


In order to review these codes and assess their relevance and implication for India, the Reserve Bank of India (RBI) established a
Standing Committee on International Financial Standards and Codes with Y. V. Reddy, the then Deputy Governor, RBI and E.A.S.
Sarma, the then Secretary, Economic Affairs, as the co-chairmen. The Standing Committee, in turn, appointed 10 Advisory Groups
to evaluate different sections of the codes, each covering specific areas. The Advisory Group headed by Montek Singh Ahluwalia
(Member, Planning Commission) examined the code on fiscal transparency and assessed the extent to which the Indian practice
complies with the code on fiscal transparency. According to the Group, ‘The overall assessment that emerges from our review is
that current fiscal practices at the central government level satisfy the minimum requirement of the Code of Good Practices on Fiscal
Transparency in many areas, though there are deficiencies in some important areas which need to be addressed. The position at the
state government level is much less satisfactory with most states being well behind the standards achieved by the central government’.
In the assessment of the Group, the areas where the Indian practices do not meet the minimum requirements are:
Central Government
Quasi-Fiscal Activities: Fiscal transparency requires that the quasi-fiscal activities performed by the government through extra-
budgetary funds or public sector entities be quantified and included in the overall fiscal reporting. Quasi-fiscal activities by such
agencies or funds are equivalent to government expenditure and should be accounted for as such. Currently, mechanisms such as
the Oil Pool Account, or the quasi-fiscal activities performed by the public sector financial institutions and enterprises are not
quantified and reported in the government budget. The Oil Pool Account, which was supposed to be a self-balancing account, has
either been in large deficits, or else in surplus, over long time periods. In the interim, these surpluses and deficits had a direct effect
on government finances as they were utilized to provide fiscal support when in surplus, and were propped up by issuing bonds when
in deficit. The quasi-fiscal activities by the public sector entities can also create contingent liabilities. This is another area of concern.
Contingent Liabilities: The code requires that the government should describe the nature and significance of the contingent liabilities,
tax expenditures and quasi-fiscal activities in the budget document. Contingent liabilities arise only in the case of specific events
on which they are based. They are equivalent to government borrowings if the contingent events were to materialize. Currently, only
the loan guarantees are reported in the central government budget. The Group points out that the letters of comfort, which are
quite similar to contingent liabilities, also go unreported. Similarly, the guarantee to meet the obligation to the Life Insurance
Fiscal and Procurement Processes 91

Corporation of India (LIC) policyholders is not listed in the budget. The recapitalization or bailouts as witnessed in the rece nt past
were realizations of implicit contingent liabilities obfuscated by the legal separation of the entities but in reality not avoi dable. While
limited information on contingent liabilities is provided in the budget, little or no information is provided on tax expenditur e and
quasi-fiscal activities associated with the same. Tax expenditures refer to the exemptions from the taxes granted by the government,
for example, allowances deducted from gross income, etc., which are similar to expenditure by the government. Such exemptions
are very large and cover both direct and indirect taxes. The tendency to use ‘exceptions’ and also varying rates has been a lasting
feature of the fiscal system, which has been only reduced a bit, with the reforms of the 1990s. There is no estimate at all of the
revenue implications of all tax expenditures and exemptions.
Clear Criteria for Administrative Discretion in Tax Laws: The fiscal transparency code requires that the criteria for administrative
discretion in tax laws and regulations should be clear leaving minimal scope for discretion and consequent harassment and corruption.
As pointed out clearly by the Group, the scope for administrative discretion arises because of large number of rates of taxes, many
possible exemptions including complex multi-criteria exemptions, besides frequent changes, etc.
Budget Preparation and Reporting: The code on fiscal transparency requires that the budget document should specify fiscal policy
objectives, the macroeconomic framework, the policy basis, and identifiable fiscal risks. The information comparable to that in the
annual budget should be provided for the previous two years. Similarly projections for two years following the budget should also
be provided. The annual budget should be prepared and presented within a comprehensive and consistent quantitative macroeconomic
framework and main assumptions should be provided. There should be an active committee of the legislature that oversees the conduct
of fiscal policy and which facilitates civil society input into the budget. Further, a mid-year report on the budget developments should
be presented to the legislature. Currently, the Indian practice falls short on these criteria, as pointed out by the Advisory Group.
The assumptions on basic macroeconomic variables are not spelt out and are probably not based on any formal model. There are
no projections for the years following. Though the Public Accounts Committee (PAC) and various standing committees of the
parliament oversee the budget, there is no practice to seek inputs from the civil society. There is a ritual meeting of the finance
minister with economistsa. The supplementary demands by various ministries are presented to the Parliament for approval but the
overall budgetary developments and implications do not accompany them.
State Governments
According to the assessment of the Advisory Group, the practices at the state government level are substantially below the standards
specified in the code. The Group did not examine these in great details but made a few observations, which are revealing enough.
In the case of state governments, the quasi-fiscal activities of state government enterprises such as the State Electricity Boards (SEBs)
and the Road Transport Corporations (RTCs) result in substantial losses and consequent degradation of the true fiscal situation,
which goes unreported except to the extent of budgetary support. Similarly, even though the state governments are supposed to raise
the loans from the market only with the approval of the central government (as long as they have outstanding dues to the central
government), they do not require similar approval for guarantees. This is often utilized to soften budget constraints. According to
the estimates reported by the Advisory Group, the contingent liabilities are about one-fourth of the total liabilities.
The total outstanding guarantees by 17 major states, according to the Group, exceed Rs 1,00,000 crore. Another common practice
reported by the Group relates to the use of contingency funds by the state governments. Contingency funds, as the name suggests,
are provided for in the budget to meet unforeseen expenditures not appropriated and approved by the legislature. Some of the states
have used this provision to accommodate large expenditures not authorized by the legislature, when the legislature is not in session.
Through an ordinance, the size of the contingency funds is increased and then the ordinance is allowed to lapse. The expenditure
is later regularized without too much of discussion in the legislature!

FISCAL RESPONSIBILITY AND BUDGET MANAGEMENT BILL, 2000


In order to contain the fiscal deficit and to set up a strong institutional mechanism to promote fiscal prudenceb, a draft fiscal
responsibility and budget management bill has been proposed but is pending with the Parliament. The bill seeks to mandate on
the central government to provide for (i) Medium-term Fiscal Policy (MTFP) Statement, (ii) Fiscal Policy Strategy Statement and
(iii) Macroeconomic Framework Statement, while presenting the annual budgeting in the Parliament. It also seeks to bind the central
government into eliminating revenue deficit within a five years’ time-frame, prohibits borrowing from the Reserve Bank of India
(RBI) and limits overall borrowing to 50 per cent of Gross Domestic Product (GDP). Though the focus of the bill is on fiscal
management, some of these measures are likely to improve transparency as well. According to the bill, the government needs to
disclose significant changes in the accounting standards, policies and practices, which may affect computation of fiscal indicators.
Similarly, it also requires the government to disclose all outstanding contractual liabilities, unrealized revenues, committed liabilities
with regard to major works and projects, losses incurred in providing public goods and services, market value of assets and liabilities
and contingent liabilities created by guarantees. It also envisages an independent review by the Fiscal Management Review Committee,
a new body proposed to be created.
a See Section 6.3 of the report.
b The objectives of the draft bill, as referred to in its preamble.
92 India Infrastructure Report 2003

4.2 PUBLIC PROCUREMENT AND THE PRIVATE SECTOR

Ajay Pandey

Any investment in the infrastructure sector by the private government hospitals, poor laying of the roads by the
sector has the aspects of some kind of procurement process contractors for the government, are some obvious examples.
by the state, unless, of course, the sector has been completely Historically, the procurement process of the government
freed from the control of the state. In most of the seems to have been designed with a view to acquire goods
infrastructure sectors, private investment is usually in the and services from the private sector with the least possible
form of private provisioning of public services licensed or cost to the exchequer. Competitive bidding (non-collusive
procured by the government. For example, the telecom practices) and the quality were attempted to be ensured
sector in India required bidding for the licence fee when through independent quality standards and audit, tight and
it was opened to the private sector. In case of roads, the detailed specifications, and internal audits.
private sector bids for the receipt of payments either through
annuity payments or actual or shadow tolls. The lowest or Incentive Incompatibilities
the highest bidder, depending upon whether it is receipt or
The bureaucracy appears to be aligned towards these goals
payment, gets the right to provide the specific service, subject
primarily through negative incentives or deterrents. Over the
to quality safeguards.
years, the effectiveness of these safeguards has proved to be
questionable. The process is vitiated either by collusion within
Inappropriate Procurement: a Constraint
the bureaucracy so that its acts of omission and commission
It is now widely recognized that inappropriate procurement go unchallenged, or by subversion of independent agencies
and post-procurement processes of the government can deter like auditors. In the case of the former, the moves towards
private investments in the infrastructure sector or can result transparency and public disclosures can be effective, particularly
in inefficient provisioning, including waste, delays and poor in countries where public awareness is high and credible
quality. Alternative procurement rules and processes4 have enforcement of deterrent punishment is likely. In the absence
implications on the incentives of the private sector, risk of these, in countries where independent agencies or institutions
allocation and how recontracting is done ex post. In this have been emasculated and where public apathy prevails, the
section, we review the determinants of effective and efficient information disclosure has very little, if at all any, effect.
procurement by the state. The motivation behind such an
exercise is that unless the procurement process itself is Complexity Needs Recognition
‘appropriate’, attracting and using private capital or the
Besides the question of inadequacy of safeguards, the
private sector for infrastructure projects per se may not lead
procurement process, which might have been appropriate
to the desired outcomes. This is especially true of
for relatively standard goods and services in the past, has,
infrastructure services where the market failures are large,
today, become inadequate for the complex projects,
and complete privatization, with only light regulation, is
technologies, equipment and services. Large variants of the
not possible.
standard as well as new procurement and post-procurement
processes have been used by governments the world-over.
Right Procurement is Crucial
In the infrastructure sector itself, different bases of bidding
Besides private-sector participation in the infrastructure (revenue-share, cost, user tariff, consolidated licence fee),
sector—hitherto restricted to the public sector—a substantial and structures (build, operate, and transfer (BOT), build,
part of government expenditure is spent in procuring goods own and operate (BOO), design, build, finance, and operate
and services from the private sector. While some of these (DBFO) etc.) used by the governments can be viewed as
may not be critical from the point of view of consumers attempts to improve the outcomes associated with private-
of public services, they could still affect them directly or sector participation through procurement-process design.
indirectly. Poor quality5 of medicines procured by the In the next sub-section, the determinants of an effective
procurement process such as the type of the project, the
4See Laffont and Tirole (1993) for review of the literature in
which the problem of procurement is seen as a problem of ex ante provides numerous references citing such problems in the US context.
information asymmetry. Rose-Ackerman (1999) discusses the attempts made by Steven Kelman
5 Poor quality and inefficient public procurement is not only an as head of Office of Federal Procurement Policy (OFPP) to improve
issue in developing countries such as India. Rose-Ackerman (1978) the effectiveness and efficiency of public procurement.
Fiscal and Procurement Processes 93

characteristics of the output, the broader legal and contractual related to time and costs of completion. The costs of a
framework and even the nature of public awareness in the project are not only the direct and indirect costs actually
country are identified and discussed. This discussion focuses incurred but also include opportunity costs arising out of
on procurement for projects or services under long-term time overruns. Projects vary in their risk-profile based on
contracts, a feature of infrastructure-sector projects. Using the interlinkages within and outside the domain of the
the reports of the Comptroller and Auditor General (CAG) project besides the technological and the project-specific
of India, the observations made by the office of CAG on uncertainties. Even the simplest of projects usually do not
procurement by the Government of India and its agencies have an engineering relationship between effort and time
are documented and analysed later in this paper. Admittedly, or costs. More complex projects have uncertainties despite
such an analysis suffers from ‘selection bias’ as only a small detailed specification and project plans, developed to
number of problem cases are highlighted by the CAG report. overcome or minimize the effects of these risks. If a third
However, it is possible that the nature of problems party, procured by the client, executes the project, the issue
documented by the office of CAG may provide insights into of risk allocation arises. The general principle of risk allocation
the weakness of procurement processes within the public is that the one who can bear it most efficiently and for
sector. CAG reports usually do not comment on the quality whom they are endogenous6 (that is, can be controlled by
of procured goods and services except when cases of poor him) should bear the risk. Effective allocation of risks leads
quality are obvious and entail easily verifiable immediate to appropriate incentives for an efficient project execution.
financial costs or losses. To that extent, the reports themselves Typically, projects where there is relatively little uncertainty
suffer from a ‘selection bias’ in having ignored or not having about the quality, quantity and the interdependencies within
recognized cases of poor quality. Finally, we conclude with the project, tend to be offered or procured on fixed fee
suggestions for reforms in public procurement. We also ‘turnkey’ basis. This process allocates the endogenous risks
bring out the limitations of these measures. of the project to the contractor. The interdependencies of
a large complex project is internalized and endogenized
Complexity of Public Procurement through turnkey award. Fragmenting the contract would
lead to coordination risks being allocated to the client.
Procurement of goods and services for the use of the public
Project procurement through fixed-fee turnkey contract
sector or for the public services provided by the public
creates incentives for the project-implementing contractor
sector, entails the decision to ‘make or buy’ the good or
to save on costs and time as any savings are retained by him.
service under consideration. All economic agents, particularly
It also creates incentives for him to innovate in order to save
firms, routinely face make, or buy, decisions. Analytically
costs. While some of these innovations could be desirable,
therefore, the considerations which play an important role
others could lead to poor quality of work if the specifications
in such decisions, are also applicable to public procurement.
are not tight enough or are not verifiable during or
However, there are important differences between the private
immediately after the execution of work. To that extent, the
sector and the public sector in the incentives, the internal
high powered incentives associated with fixed fee contracts7
controls, the budget constraints, the ability to use the legal
may be perverse if the quality-attributes of the work or
and contractual framework, and the role of markets and
project elements are not amenable to effective monitoring
society. These differences can result in very different outcomes
or verification, ex post.
for the two sectors even when following a given procurement
On the other hand, cost-plus contracts, in terms of risk
process. Henceforth, we first review the generic con-
allocation and incentives, clearly retain project related risks
siderations in procurement, viz., risk allocation, incentive
with the client and present no incentives to undertake
effects, information asymmetry, quality controls and all the
innovations both in a negative and positive sense. They are
relevant costs such as project costs, operating costs,
used when the information asymmetry between the client
transaction costs, recontracting costs and opportunity costs,
and the contractor is high, the requirements are difficult to
etc. Later, we bring out how the key differences between
specify ex-ante, and when the quality is difficult to verify.
the public sector and the private sector induce different
outcomes.
6 This simply means that he is the best placed to reduce the same.
7 While fixed fee turnkey contracts may resolve the problem of
ISSUES IN PROCUREMENT the bidder having superior information ex ante, the high-powered
incentives that go along with such contract create difficulties for ex
Risk Allocation and Incentives post adaptations (Williamson, 1985). Need for ex post adaptations
arises when there are uncertainties about the project design and the
Unlike relatively standard goods or services, execution of environmental conditions, such as in the case of construction contracts,
any reasonably complex project entails considerable risks projects, etc.
94 India Infrastructure Report 2003

Accordingly, both cost-plus as well as turnkey contracts the possibility of costly renegotiations and recontracting.
are used extensively depending upon the attributes of the Earnest money deposits, performance guarantees and
project. In the case of most engineering-driven projects, like liquidated damages are similarly attempts to minimize the
setting up of production plants, fixed-fee contracts are used. possibility of non-performance by a bidder facing winner’s
In cases like drilling8 of oil wells, since the entire project curse.
is difficult to specify ex-ante (exact depth, geological features,
various tests and even completion criterion), the services are Incomplete Contracts, Recontracting and Opportunity
hired on cost-plus (daily rates) basis. Similarly, most of the Costs
software development projects, which cannot be specified
Despite developing detailed plans and specifications before
completely, are given out on cost-plus basis.
project procurement, all procurement contracts are essentially
incomplete. Some changes in quantity or specifications based
Information Asymmetry and Winner’s Curse
on experiences during the course of project implementation
The procurement process has to take into account the chance are always likely. In some cases, these may be minor and
of severe information asymmetry between the client and the in some others fairly major. The contracts, besides laying
contractor with regard to the tasks entailed by the project, down the obligations in specified situations, also provide a
besides risk allocation and issues of incentive compatibility. framework for renegotiations through change-order clauses.
If the client knows more about the effort involved or the If major changes are expected, as would be the case when
likely cost of the project, the client ought to bear the risks the project details have not been worked out or are likely
associated with the activity and the bidder when he knows to evolve, then the costs involved in recontracting10 are also
more. Otherwise, the winning bidder or contractor is likely severe. In case of failed negotiations, these may involve cost
to face what is known as winner’s curse. Winner’s curse9 of retendering and consequent delay. If the project is ‘time-
arises when a winning bidder or contractor underestimates critical’ and has substantial opportunity costs, other costs
the effort required in completing the project and thereby involved in the procurement are likely to take a back seat.
faces a loss-making situation despite winning the bid for the Cost-plus contracts and non-competitive procurement, such
project. In such cases, cost-plus contracts with close as emergency purchases from pre-identified vendors, tend
monitoring by the client may be desirable despite being to be used to minimize such costs.
non-incentive compatible. Even if there is no information
asymmetry between the client and the bidder or the Item Specificity, Industry Structure and Reputation
contractor, the problem of winner’s curse can arise in cases Effects
where there is great uncertainty about project cost and effort
If the product or project being procured by the client is
requirement. The winning bid is more likely to be the one
specific11 to the client, then the production technology and
that underestimated the effort requirement and quoted low.
the presence of substitutes become key determinants of the
Facing winner’s curse ex post, either the bidder would
procurement process. In the absence of substitutes, complete
try and wriggle out of the contract or would try and
mutual dependence leads to bilateral negotiations and long-
compromise on the quality. Bidders are likely to quote
term contracts, as no party would like the other one to hold
higher ex ante if they are aware that ex post they cannot
it to ransom. In case the production technology for producing
do either. In such a situation, disclosing as much information
the goods or services warrants investments by the supplier
about the project as possible helps in mitigating consequences
or the contractor, which are likely to be sunk and
of winner’s curse problem. Meetings called for clarifications
by the potential bidders and development of detailed
10 Bajari and Tadelis (2001) have developed a model incorporating
tendering documents as part of the standard procurement
incentives and transaction costs and show that cost-plus contracts
process can be viewed as steps in the direction of disclosing
would be preferred when a project is more complex and when time-
and sharing project-related information. These, of course, to-completion is critical. They also explain the prevalence of basic
also help in the enforcement of the contract and in reducing cost-plus and turnkey contracts over other complex incentive contracts.
They show that internal production dominates market procurement
8 Corts (2002) empirically analyses the role of adverse selection, when the product is more complex.
risk sharing, scale economies, incentives and transaction costs in 11 This is known as ‘hold-up problem’ in the literature, (Grout,
offshore drilling in the Gulf of Mexico, where both day-rate and (1984). When the product or project requires investments in assets
turnkey contracts have been used. Even the turnkey contracts are by a seller, which are specific to a buyer, the buyer can hold-up and
converted to day rates if there is a storm or a particular geological arm-twist the seller as contracts are incomplete. A reverse ‘hold-up’
formation is encountered while drilling. problem can also arise if the buyer buys a product, which has to be
9 Winner’s Curse in auctions is a well-known result. See Milgrom maintained and kept in operating condition only with the seller’s
(1989) for an intuitive review of research in Auction Theory. support (in terms of consumables, spares, services, etc.).
Fiscal and Procurement Processes 95

irrecoverable, then the long-term contract specifying user’s assessment of the quality may be quite different from
minimum quantity and price is the only way out. On the that of the procurement agent. Worse still, the possibility
other hand, if the investments are not specific or are of collusion between the procurement agent and the supplier
recoverable, then the dependence of the supplier on the becomes strong in case the incentives of the agent and the
client is less, and more competition on the supplier side is user are not correctly aligned. In case of weak incentive
likely and desirable. A related issue is the presence of alignment between the end-user and his procurement agent,
economies of either scale or scope or both in the production the procurement process is likely to be driven by the
technology. In the presence of these, long-term contracts incentives of the procurement agent which may compromise
with a single or a few suppliers would be superior even if the quality. Monitoring and certification by the end-
the investment required by the suppliers is not sunk but is consumer is usually the first-best solution and in the presence
recoverable. Long-term contracts with limited competition of difficulties, such as existence of a free-rider problem, an
in such cases create high-powered incentives for product or independent agent may be used in lieu of the end-consumer.
project-specific innovations to reduce costs (to exploit An independent agent may also be desirable when the
economies of scale) and to deliver quality (to build reputation quality verification may call for complex and technical
in order to exploit economies of scope). Promoting analysis, which the end-consumer cannot do.
competition in such cases, on the other hand, may be To sum up, procurement raises issues related to risk-
counter-productive as it weakens the reputation effect12. In allocation, information asymmetry, transaction costs and
case significant product- or project-specific investment is quality. As a result, design of procurement process and choice
required, such a strategy is infeasible, as the investments of procurement policies for optimal outcomes are likely to
would not be made in the absence of long-term contracts. be influenced by the characteristics of product or services
This is commonly cited as the rationale behind vendor being procured, the characteristics of the supplier industry,
development and long-term relationship with the vendor. the legal-contractual framework and how time-critical the
procurement is. Procurement can also be classified into four
Monitoring, Independent Inspections and Quality stylized categories15: procurement requiring R&D or client-
specific investment, procurement of complex projects,
In case of product procurement, the uncertainty about
procurement of standard goods available in the market and
quality is much lower as long as quality attributes are clearly
procurement of customized goods otherwise sold in the
known13 and can be inspected. But, even in such cases,
market. In case of the first type, the main issue is the
there could be quality attributes which are difficult to verify
effectiveness of the procurement and the issues therein are
and test at the time of procurement. Usually, prior experience
extremely complex. In such cases, which are relatively few,
and reputation supplement the inspections and tests to
the risks have to be borne by the buyer. It is the second and
ensure quality in procurement. This issue becomes more
the last types, which are also most common, that require
prominent when the quality is not easily verifiable, as the
careful procurement design. The third type is relatively trivial
quality attributes are complex, multi-dimensional, many,
for a bulk-buyer as the procurement can be off-the-shelf
and interdependent. In the case where the user14 is different
possibly adjusting for any bulk-buying discount. In the context
from the procurement agent, complications arise, as the
of the private sector, the separation of the procurement agent
from the end-user is less of an issue as the corporate control
12 Banerjee and Daflo (2000) document that older Indian IT
structure is likely to address this problem and, in any case,
firms are more likely to be engaged on cost-plus basis for providing the effect of sub-optimal procurement is internalized16 by
customized software and for more complex projects. They interpret
age as a measure of reputation.
the entity particularly in a competitive product-market.
13 If the quality can be specified completely ex ante and ensured
ex post, then auctions can be an effective procurement mechanism.
Bos and Kolmar (2000) argue that poor specifiability of quality is
ISSUES IN PUBLIC PROCUREMENT
one of the reasons why public procurement does not have the structure
of an auction. Tiefer and Shook (1999) report that the government
In case of public procurement, the issues related to
in the US commonly carries out competitive negotiations for procurement are compounded by the distinct characteristics
procurement above US $100,000.
14 What we mean here is the end-user, and not the ostensible or 15 This classification has been used by Rose-Ackerman (1999) to
immediate user (buyer) of the product or service. If the immediate analyse public procurement and the policy prescription for eliminating
user is different from the eventual end-user and is the one who corruption from public procurement. The conclusion discussed in
decides, the problem simply shifts from the procurement agent to this this paragraph are based on her analysis.
immediate user. If, however, the immediate user and end-users’ interests 16 Unless the management uses procurement to further its own
are aligned, then shifting the locus of decision-making might indeed interest at the expense of the shareholders—not an uncommon situation
result in a superior outcome. but, possibly, not as rampant as it is in public procurement.
96 India Infrastructure Report 2003

of the procurement agent and the public services for which extract payoffs by compromising on quality. Delays can be
procurement takes place. Unlike the case of more normal used to extract payoffs, because often the cost of waiting
products and services, where markets exist and can be is higher for the supplier than the public servant. Such
expected to perform, the absence of markets and, therefore, extractions need not be limited to the surplus. They could
lack of choice or substitutes for its consumers, characterize come out of normal profits of the supplier or, what is more
public services. Even if they face competition, the public likely, through compromises in quantity and quality. This
entities providing them face relatively soft-budget constraints can happen when the investment is sunk and waiting is
compared to their private counterparts. The public entities costly. Payments, even when due, may be released only
are more likely to be propped up by the government using when the bribe is paid. The suppliers, knowing the delays
exchequers’ funds. Worse still, even if the budget constraints and the side-payments involved, would increase the amount
are tightened due to resource constraints, the effect is not they bid for or lower the quality of product or services. In
on those who retain the locus of control on the relevant case of reputation effects, when the product being supplied
decisions but on the other employees. This makes public is also sold in the market, this would result in self-selection.
procurement one of the important focus areas in any debate Only suppliers with poor quality of products would be then
on governance. supplying to the government.

Externalities and Weak Incentives Corruption and Anti-Competitive Procurement


The lack of incentive compatibility between the procurement In the absence of corruption, the problems related to
agent and the end-user in the context of public procurement procurement are similar in both the private and the public
is quite severe. The consequences of products and services sectors. Corruption, or the use of public office for private
procured by the public servants have very limited, if at all gains, manifests itself in the form of poor quality or higher
any, effect on them. As a result, negative externalities arise. costs of public procurement. In case the quality is easily
The costs of any sub-standard or costly product or service verifiable ex post, such as in the case of procurement of
procurement are borne by the users of the public service for standard goods and commodities, and when the corrupt
which it was procured, or by the taxpayers. Because of officials face reasonably high probability of detection and
difficulties in aligning the public servants’ interest with that associated penalty, then anti-competitive and costly
of their principal—the public—the public servants have procurement process is a method to generate personal
very little incentives to procure the best. They may instead payoffs. If the seller is able to earn surplus due to absence
have incentives to procure what gives them maximum payoffs. of competition, it is easy to extract a part of this surplus
The only real incentive is the negative one of being caught as bribe. Anti-competitive procurement can be organized
violating the guidelines and the ex ante controls in multiple ways. Specifications could be chosen either to
circumscribing the procurement process. Collectively, these favour some sellers or as entry barriers for others. Non-
negative incentives can also be overcome easily through standard items may be procured instead of relatively standard
collusion and by diffusing the responsibility. The items. Non-standard product or services, even if ostensibly
specifications can be chosen to suit some bidders or a cheaper, may increase the possibility of ‘hold-up’ by the
contractor, lax standards can be used or only certain type seller later and thus increase their life-cycle costs. For
of bidders could be allowed. Even independent agencies can example, purchase of equipment having lower up-front
be co-opted to qualify poor quality or unproven bidders, costs may, later, make the buyer dependent on the seller for
and poor quality, or even non-existent, work can be paid spares, if they are non-standard and use proprietary
for. In short, while the letter and the form of the procurement technology. Red tape or delays and other bureaucratic devices
guidelines and processes are maintained, the spirit may be can be used to erect entry barriers selectively. If the quality
violated. Ex post reviews and prosecutions are difficult, if is also difficult to verify or selective response18 is given to
not impossible, when the process and ex ante controls have quality variations due to incompleteness of the contracts,
been complied with. then anti-competitive procurement becomes even more
lucrative.
Red Tape
Red tape, or bureaucratic delays, can be effectively used to 18 If the contract has deliberate gaps in specs, then acceptance of
increase the bargaining power17 of the public servants to quality delivered with respect to the gaps is open to selective review
extract surplus from the supplier. It can also be used to by the public official. He can then accept the gaps or he can impose
costs on the seller if he decides to fill in the gaps. This discretion,
when used selectively, can erect an effective entry barrier for an
17 See Rose-Ackerman (1978). ‘honest’ supplier.
Fiscal and Procurement Processes 97

Political Capital, Procurement and Fragmentation examples. Extraction of surplus from the consumers and the
exchequer using public procurement becomes the main
As opposed to the public officials, the politicians have
objective of many individuals. In fact, such individuals are
usually preference for payoffs in both pecuniary and political
more likely to enter politics to protect the criminal empire
terms. In particular, they also need to generate political
created on the back of public procurement. Poor qualification
capital from the decision taken by the public officials being
standards set for the suppliers usually provide initial
controlled by them. While centralization and aggregation
motivation and incentives and over a period of time, some
of procurement suits them for the former, fragmentation of
of them either become less dependent on public procurement
the public procurement suits their requirement to generate
or become politicians or both. The implications of such self-
political capital better. If favour is granted to a large number
reinforcing behaviour on the quality of public procurement
of sellers or service providers, it helps them to generate
are obvious.
political capital. On the other hand, such a move dissipates
the bribes collected because of difficulties in collection and
Difficulties in Recontracting
bargaining through middlemen. In a political system in
which the politicians cannot generate political capital19, Unlike the private sector, the public sector finds
there would be a tendency to a higher level of corruption renegotiations and recontracting much more difficult. This
and centralized procurement. In case procurement cannot is mainly because of ex ante (procedural) controls and the
be used to generate political capital, centralized and public gaze. If any major change is required in a contract,
aggregated procurement would be preferred. Both and the contract had not provided for such a possibility or
aggregation and fragmentation have certain undesirable had specified limits to such changes, public officials find it
characteristics and could be sub-optimal in a given case. In difficult to renegotiate, and usually prefer to stick to the
case of aggregation, it might be easier to monitor and ensure contractual provisions for the fear of audit objections or
quality as well as prices, but aggregation results in increased controversies. Examples of this kind are to be found in
coordination and longer lead times and therefore, higher software development projects20, where it is difficult to
likelihood of quantity errors. Aggregation may bring in specify all the requirements upfront. Later, once the
additional benefits if the orders are given to relatively larger requirements are known and entail larger effort than planned,
suppliers or bidders, as they might be more sensitive to the suppliers find it difficult to renegotiate with the public
reputational effect and might be monitored more by the sector. Even if the costlier supplier is engaged to retendering
public and the media. In case of services, particularly when and incurring transaction costs, after it is prefered to
there are economies of scale and scope (outside the public renegotiations.
sector); large service providers are likely to be more sensitive
to quality. Fragmentation in such a case would clearly be Limits of Disclosures, Public Awareness and Other
sub-optimal. Fragmentation of procurement also weakens Deterrents
the incentives for making investments in innovations. On
Given the severe incentive problems, aligning the interest of
the other hand, for relatively standard items, which can be
public officials with that of the public is a difficult challenge.
easily procured from a competitive market, it aligns the user
Since divergence of the incentives of the public official is
requirement better with the procurement.
at the core of most of the public procurement problems, any
change in the institutional framework or reforms per se are
Collusion, Anti-Competitive Behavior and Quality Issues
not likely to be effective without addressing this problem.
As argued earlier, anti-competitive procurement policies For example, shifting the point of discretion simply results
can be used effectively by the public officials to line their in change in the locus of the problem. Centralization increases
pockets. Similarly, anti-competitive behaviour by the high-level corruption while decentralization increases petty
suppliers can generate rents for the suppliers. In collusion ones. If discretion is vested with multiple agencies, it results
with the public officials, the suppliers can form informal in turf fights, eventually leading to the dominance of one
cartels to create entry-barriers. Such cartels and monopolies or the collusion among many.
evolve over a period of time and rely on criminal activities Unlike bureaucratic restructuring, reforms aimed at direct
to prevent entry. In the Indian context, labour and public control by the public, such as disclosures, users’ feedback,
works contracts and liquor-vending licences are prime etc., may be more effective but have their limitations too.
19 For example, if everyone votes for the party and not for the 20 This is based on personal experience, gained while developing
individual in the elections. The effect would be the same in a case cases on such projects for a large Indian IT firm. Not allowing
where political capital generated is local in character but the effects renegotiations when the monitoring is difficult and incentives are
of procurement are outside this domain. perverse is, however, appropriate to prevent collusion.
98 India Infrastructure Report 2003

Information-processing capacity with the public is limited procurement-related public expenditure is incurred due to
and it has limited incentive to process the information due (a) lack of information and coordination across various
to free-rider problems. Activism may help provided the governmental agencies, (b) fragmenting the project execution,
public supports such activism. If activism itself is driven by (c) unnecessary procurement advised by the consultants,
private interests cynicism may take root instead. Activists, and (d) the inability or the difficulty in taking the decision
on the other hand, face low incentives if their actions have to liquidate or discontinue.
a low possibility of affecting any change. Legal and judicial In this section, only the issues and examples related to
measures, such as public interest litigation or complaints, lack of coordination among various agencies are discussed.
are costly and rely upon enforcement by the state (controlled While the private sector always complains of lack of
by the executive) to be effective. Immunities available to the coordination among various governmental agencies resulting
public servants, coupled with secrecy, limit the effectiveness in delays in clearances and uncertainties, the problem affects
of prosecution as a deterrent. Speedy and exemplary the government agencies as well. Whereas the private sector
punishments21 through judicial processes, along with increase may respond by delaying the investments, it seems
in disclosure, can however be effective at the high-level and governmental agencies do not mind investing as long as
may also weaken collusion between various agencies of the some promises and clearances are obtained. The expected
state. diligence exercise is either not undertaken or is ineffective.
Some examples of this kind are provided in the CAG
SOME ILLUSTRATIONS FROM CAG REPORTS report. Non-acquisition of land from the Air Force has been
cited, as one of the major reasons why the Yashwantpur–
The office of the Comptroller and Auditor General of India Salem gauge conversion project undertaken by the Railways
(CAG) is an independent auditor of all the transactions and could not be made fully operational. Another reason cited
expenditure of the union and state governments, including is the demand for a road over-bridge by the local population,
public-sector enterprises. It compiles an annual review of which required coordination with the state government.
the expenditure and its audit observations in the form of Similarly, a metre gauge (MG) branch line between New
Union and State Audit Reports. In this section, some parts MalBazar–Damohoni in NEF Railway was restored (it had
of the CAG Union Audit Report 2000–1 are reviewed to been abandoned due to floods in 1968) at a cost of Rs 25.64
ascertain the kind of problems that have been highlighted crore in 2000, which, thereafter, became gauge-locked! This
by the CAG with regard to public procurement. In particular, happened because, in 1999, the Railways decided that the
focus is laid on sectors such as Railways, Ports, Roads and existing Siliguri–New Bongaigaon MG mainline would be
Petroleum. These are some of the sectors which are important converted in broad gauge. In case of the public sector oil
to infrastructure and involve the private sector as suppliers. companies, Bharat Petroleum Corporation Limited (BPCL)
This review has been motivated by the desire to identify and and IBP decided sometime in 1989–90 to invest in the
characterize the nature of problems in public procurement construction of a product depot at Muzaffarpur in Bihar as
as highlighted by the CAG and is not meant to validate or the crude from Assam for Barauni refinery was not adequate
support the problems identified by the CAG. Accordingly, the for its operations. The construction for the depot was started
examples given in this section are not evidences of the in 1995 and completed in 1997. Meanwhile in 1993, Indian
propositions advanced and are based on the limited information Oil Corporation (IOC) planned a crude pipeline from the
given in these reports. eastern coast to reduce the dependence of its Barauni refinery
on Assam crude. The project was completed later. As a
Unnecessary Investments and Procurements result, the product depot remained non-operational since
its construction. In a similar vein, the Durgapur unit of
As a class, unnecessary investments or procurement have
Hindustan Fertilizers Limited procured capital good worth
invited the maximum number of the CAG’s audit
Rs 11.08 crore in anticipation of clearance for revival of the
observations. Some of the decisions, which lead to
unit, which had not been received till the date of writing
unnecessary expenditure, are taken at the policy level and
are driven by political considerations and may not have any of the CAG report (October 2001). As per the CAG report,
economic justification. The decision of creation of new the Air Force developed a golf course in an area reserved
zones by the Railways would fit this category. The creation for storage of explosives! In another instance of a similar
of new zones has been criticized not only by the CAG in kind, the CAG reports that Hindustan Petroleum Company
its 1999–2000 report, but also by other experts. Unnecessary Limited (HPCL) constructed 3 ATF tanks at Vijaywada at
a cost of Rs 3.25 crore without ascertaining its linkage to
21
East Asian societies such as Korea in the past, China today, Hyderabad and Secunderabad. These are just a few
Taiwan, etc. have used these very effectively. illustrations of the procurement agency within the
Fiscal and Procurement Processes 99

government either lacking information or not being able to when the collusion is not complete and it results in the users
coordinate its procurement with other agencies, ultimately or inspectors rejecting the procured item, such cases do get
leading to sub-optimal or wasteful procurement. The distance reported. The chances of such rejection are dependent on
between the decision-makers and the implementing agency, how critical the procurement was and how the payoffs were
lack of information or of selective information being made shared. A few instances of this kind have been reported in
available to the decision-makers, ‘accountability and reviews’ the CAG report. Some of them might have been deliberate
driven by the fund utilization accompanied by long approval and some inadvertent (due to incompetence). One such
processes, perverse incentives in the absence of effective example is the procurement of Balau sleepers from Malaysia
monitoring by the public and absence of deterrents, all by the Railways, involving a sum of Rs 20 crore. The
contribute to this problem in their own ways. Railway Board, against the recommendations of the Forest
Research Institute (FRI) cleared the imports. Later, the
Fragmented Projects and Procurement officers charged with the task of inspection and assurance
cleared the sleepers imported by Indian firms, despite their
Besides the problem of coordination among government
being of sub-standard quality. Similarly, Chennai Port Trust
agencies, fragmentation of projects with independent
paid an excess of Rs 8.72 crore for construction of
implementation is another reason which leads to idle or
breakwaters, as it had forgotten to deduct the value of rock
unnecessary investments. For example22, the transmission
supplied, before making payments. Some of the strategies
lines for a project like Nathpa–Jhakri have been laid even
followed in collusion with the suppliers are (a) quantity
though the hydel project itself has slipped far behind.
variations or changes in specification ex post to favour the
Similarly, in case of gauge conversion projects on the Miraj–
contractor in case of projects, (b) booking and paying for
Latur section, the priorities were changed midway leaving
fictitious work where measurements are difficult to verify,
completed assets in some parts of the section, which would
such as earthwork, (c) accepting poor quality product or
go waste. While, in the case of the former, the implementation
work and (d) coming up with ingenious requirements and
was by two different agencies, in the latter case it was by
arguments in favour of the contractor or the supplier. An
the Railways itself. Besides fragmentation of projects, which
example of the last is provided in the CAG report, where
is against the basics of project management, fragmentation
the leasing option for a crane was favoured by making
of procurement orders for services also reduces the incentive
biased comparisons. According to the report, the NPV of
of suppliers to build reputation. In the case of catering23
purchase option was calculated by applying cost of capital
for the Railways, as many as 1111 private-sector contractors
at 12 per cent, which was not applied in the case of the lease
operated, as on April 2000. This lessens their individual
option by the Cochin Port. The ingenious argument put
incentive to improve quality and also that of the consumers
forward in its defence was that a lease was a revenue
to monitor them. While fragmented procurement may have
expenditure and, hence, interest need not be factored in
the advantage that goods or services are procured depending
evaluating lease options. According to CAG, the concerned
on the specific local requirements and are procured as and
ministry also endorsed the Cochin Port’s viewpoint.
when required, this cannot be the major factor in the context
of catering in the Railways. Similarly, there are too many
Winner’s Curse and Ineffective Processes
private contractors from whom vehicles are contracted by
the road transport corporations (RTCs). While it is possible As discussed earlier in this section, winner’s curse is likely
to argue that the ostensibly poor quality is economically to be faced by the winning bidder when the degree of
efficient given the income level of consumers, it is not incompleteness of the contract is high or when the competing
certain whether the poor quality is not accompanied by bidders have information advantage. The problem gets
rents earned by the contractors or by the RTC officials. It compounded when the cause of the winner’s curse problem
is also evident that a large section of consumers are dissatisfied is endogenous (that is, when the buyer can use the contract
with the quality. to his advantage to increase the scope and is driven by
perverse incentives). Facing such a situation, the bid would
Collusion with the Contractor be pitched higher to account for the possibility of a winner’s
curse. Moreover, such a bid would take into account the
Collusion between the contractor or supplier and the
ability to control endogenous causes, the performance fee
procurement agency to maximize their own payoffs is one
put up upfront, etc. For example, if the earnest money and
major problem with public procurement. By the very nature
bank guarantees are structured in such a manner that the
of these arrangements, it is difficult to detect them. However,
incremental gains from reneging on the contract is costlier
22 This example is not from the CAG report. compared to continuation, then continuation would be
23 See Raghuram (2002). preferred. The other alternative would be to do shoddy
100 India Infrastructure Report 2003

work (incur minimum incremental costs) and somehow protecting or supporting domestic, or a class of firms. The
complete contractual obligations. In the context of public latter was particularly used in the past when the thrust of
procurement, allowing ex post renegotiations can create economic policy itself was on import substitution and on
perverse incentives and, therefore, detailing the specifications protection24 of small-scale enterprises. The consequences,
ex ante is to be preferred. In some cases, however, such however, may not always be desirable as the quality of
detailing may not be feasible and the problem remains. procurement may suffer. On the other hand, procurements
Some manifestations of this problem are pointed out in the on the basis of limited tender in emergency situations are
CAG report. For the Arsikere–Hassan–Managalore gauge particularly prone to misuse, as the urgency of procurement
conversion project of Southern Railways, 14 contractors is partly endogenous to the procurement agency. Poor
(with whom 17 contracts were entered into) failed on various planning or deliberate omission of some of the items can
works between 1995–2000. Of these 17 contracts, 10 failed force urgent procurement later. A couple of examples of this
after the work had been started and seven without the work kind from the CAG report illustrate these issues. In the case
even having been commenced. The total cost recoverable of the Tehri Hydro Development Corporation, CAG reports
from the contractors, on account of their failure, was Rs that 13 contracts valued at Rs 8.96 crore were awarded on
1.78 crore but only Rs 0.14 crore were collected. Since the the basis of limited tenders for various on-going works
performance guarantees were not insisted upon, such related to rehabilitation on grounds of urgency. Otherwise,
processes would have invariably led to aggressive bidding any work-order above the value of Rs 1 lakh required open
and, hence, the failures and abandonment of the contracts. tendering. CAG’s comments have to be seen in the backdrop
In an earlier case of bidding by the telecom operators for of the slow progress of rehabilitation.
basic telephony, the government revised the condition of In the case of the Railways, the production of concrete
how many circles each bidder could bid ex post, which had sleepers by the domestic firms began in 1972–3. By the year
the effect of bailing out those who had bid aggressively. A 1992–3, 73 such manufacturers existed and only 75 per
bidder, who knows that conditions would be revised later, cent of their capacity was being utilized. Initially, these
would obviously bid differently. Another example in the sleepers were being procured on the basis of limited quotes
CAG report is that of the Mudkhed–Adilabad gauge by different zones. Repeat orders were placed after examining
conversion project awarded to a firm in 1996 on Build, costs. Given the number of manufacturers and their capacity
Own, Lease and Transfer (BOLT) basis at a cost of Rs utilization, way back in 1993, the finance directorate
159.96 crore. Initially in the tender, the bidder was expected suggested procurement through open tender. However, the
to provide bank guarantees to the tune of 5 per cent of bare first open tender was floated only in 1997, in which the
construction costs including interest, which, in this case, prices were considerably lower than the repeat orders placed
was Rs 8.50 crore. After the issue of the tender, the Railway in the interim. In case of asset specificity (procurement of
Board revised the contractual provisions for the contracts items not sold to anyone else) and economies of scale,
on BOLT basis by bringing in a cap of Rs 2 crore for bank competition can be easily curbed in favour of the supplier
guarantees. The firm appealed for bringing down its bank or suppliers of a substitute, who do not face the problem
guarantee obligations, which was accepted and the lease of asset specificity. This simply requires the absence of
rentals were reduced after negotiation to reflect the savings assured orders. No supplier of such a product would invest
to the firm due to lower bank guarantee requirements. unless he is assured of orders, even if the product is superior.
Subsequently the firm failed to progress on the contract and CAG points out that, in the absence of regular orders the
requested for it to be assigned to its sister concern. Even replacement of wooden sleeper turnouts with concrete ones
this firm failed to perform and only 14 per cent earthwork has been slow, despite a successful trial in 1989, as no
and 15 per cent ballast supply was done. Even though the manufacturer would invest in manufacturing of concrete
negotiations did bring down the rentals, the effect of lowering sleeper turnouts without an assurance of regular orders.
the value of bank guarantee in removing any incentive to
complete the contract was clearly not understood or factored Softening Budget Constraints through Costly Procurement
in the negotiations.
Unlike in the private sector, it is difficult to impose hard
budget constraints on public entities. Even when they face
Anti-Competitive Procurement Policies
resource crunch, in the absence of budgetary support, they
Even when the open procurement is generally the norm, have the tendency to find ways to relax budget constraints.
many exceptions are allowed when they can be justified. At For example, leasing might be preferred over purchase as
least in two cases, exceptions are being made. These are: (a)
procurement required urgently and (b) when procurement 24 See Morris et al. (2001) for the implications of reservation for
policies favour domestic or specific firms on grounds of small-scale enterprises in public procurement.
Fiscal and Procurement Processes 101

it entails revenue expenditure and phases out the obligations. earlier, it was pointed out that FRI did point out the
The lease obligations are not capitalized and hence not unsuitability of the sleepers but was overruled. In an example
accounted for as debt. Similarly, a firm may be created to of unnecessary procurement as pointed out by the CAG,
borrow from the capital market, which is then not accounted JawaharLal Nehru Port Trust (JNPT) procured 2-bag stacker
for as public debt. In fact, the Railways have been using the reclaimers worth Rs 8.93 crore in 1989 on the recommen-
Indian Railways Finance Corporation (IRFC) for this dation of a consultant, which were never used later. The
purpose. And the erstwhile department of telecommu- system, meant for handling fertilizer and food grain bags,
nications used Mahanagar Telephone Nigam Limited had design deficiency and was not necessary.
(MTNL) for its borrowing needs. When budget constraints
are softened using leasing options it can lead to costly Bias against Liquidation and Unnecessary Procurement
procurement. An illustration of this is the Own Your Wagon
(OYW) scheme25 of the Indian Railways. The scheme was An agent working for a principal is likely to be biased
launched in 1992 to allow bulk users to own their wagons against liquidation if his own welfare depends on
and lease it to Railways. Pure financing or leasing companies continuation. This problem also creeps in the context of
could also participate. There were three categories of owners, public procurement as assets are not disposed off and
in terms of benefits. Category A was pure lease in which unnecessary expenditure is incurred even when it is clearly
the owners would be paid at the rate of 14.5 per cent (later wasteful. Absence of hard budget constraint aggravates the
revised to 16 per cent) of procurement price for the first situation further. This issue also acquires prominence in the
10 years (primary lease period) and at the rate of 1 per cent context of privatization programmes where the demand risk
for the next 10 years. Category B owners of general-purpose is not borne by the private sector. In such cases, assets and
wagons were entitled to the lease charges as above and were services may be continued even when their liquidation is
guaranteed clearance of mutually acceptable pre-specified optimal. While sub-optimal assets are difficult to identify,
quantum of load at normal tariff rates. Category C was for CAG provides an example of this problem in the form of
special wagons, which moved on dedicated routes and an extreme case. The narrow-gauge section between Latur
entailed empty running in one direction. In this case, and Miraj had 195 wagons, which were being used for a
mutually agreed lump sum freight rates were to be negotiated limited cement and Petroleum, Oil and Lubricants (POL)
and lease rental was not payable. Initially, the wagons could traffic. Most of these were over-aged wagons and, in any
be procured directly (from Railways-approved wagon case, the traffic was non-existent. Despite that, expenditure
builders) or indirectly through the Railways. Later, in 1999, to the tune of Rs 1.33 crore has been incurred on their
the policy was revised to allow procurement only through periodic overhaul over the last 10 years. Later 91 of these
the Railways. Meanwhile, 1725 wagons were allowed to be wagons were condemned after audit observations.
procured directly at a higher cost between 1995 and 1997.
Clearly, the cost of procuring wagons through OYW scheme A Classic Case of Exploiting Quantity Variation
was not kept in mind while allowing for procurement directly.
Despite open competition, detailed specifications and other
procedural controls, it is well known among the participants
Role of Consultants
in public procurement programmes that incompleteness of
Theoretically, an independent consultant can improve the the contract can be used to earn rents despite side payments
outcomes when public procurement faces problems of if ex post quantity variations can be influenced or foreseen
perverse incentives by recommending more efficient choices. with the help of insiders. In a composite bid, if the quotes
But this presumes that the independent consultant is truly are lower for those items whose tentative quantities are high
independent, his recommendations are agreed to and the and the actual is likely to be low, and vice-versa, then the
implementing agency also is willing to implement suggested winning bid can still be profitable ex post. Alternatively, if
solutions. In other words, it assumes that there is an all- the variations on profitable components can be arranged
round desire to obtain the best results. It is easy to see that with the help of the independent consultants later, then due
these conditions are unlikely to be met in reality. Consultants to the quotes, as well as due to the increase in bargaining
may be used to pass on the responsibility of unnecessary power, rents can be earned on an ostensibly less profitable
procurements, to cause delays, to change the specifications project. Usually this is done in a manner so subtle that it
midway in collusion. Their recommendations can also be does not raise any eyebrows, as there are no violations of
easily overruled in case they are inconvenient. In the case procedures. But a crude example of this has been pointed
of the Balau sleeper imports by the Railways mentioned out by the CAG. For gauge conversion work between the
Kulam and Vasco da Gama section of South-Central Railway,
25 See Raghuram (2002). tenders were invited for the execution of earthwork and
102 India Infrastructure Report 2003

minor reaches in 1995. Initially limited tenders were invited stronger deterrents, and increase in the independence of the
for the work, but later open tenders were invited after the various arms within the bureaucracy are other possibilities.
Railway Board found the rates to be high. Agreements were In this section, is discussed the rationale for these suggestions
signed in September 1995 and completed. On audit scrutiny, and their limits in improving the outcomes of public
it was found that in seven of these agreements prices quoted procurement are pointed out.
for different items of earthwork were quite suspicious. These
items constituted a substantial part of the value of work Project/Product-specific Procurement Process Design or
awarded. Of the three types of earthwork, ‘cutting in all Standardization
soils’ required the least effort but was quoted at a high rate.
Based on her experience and work at the World Bank and
‘Cutting in rock not requiring blasting’ and ‘cutting in rock
at Transparency International, Rose-Ackerman (1999),
requiring blasting’ should have been quoted at increasingly
suggests procurement policies26 to minimize the effect of
higher rates but the quotes ran in an opposite direction.
corruption in the procurement process. She suggests that
While clearing the quotations based on initial estimated
the standard product already being sold in the market can
quantities, the tender committee recommended safeguards
be procured from the market and its prices can be
that there should not be any major upward variation in
benchmarked with that of the market. Similarly, the
items quoted at high rates, whereas the quantities for items
procurement of large complex projects such as dams, ports,
with low rates should be attained. But this observation was
etc., which do not require advances in technology can be
not incorporated in the agreement. Later, the quantities
procured through sealed bidding process under International
involved in the actual execution of different items were
Competitive Bidding (ICB), as required by the World Bank.
highest for highest quoted item and lowest for lowest quoted
She acknowledges the difficulties when the procurement is
item. In case of one agreement, the quantity for ‘cutting in
that of customized products or solutions, otherwise traded
all soils’, which was estimated to be 50 units turned out to
in the market and that of complex projects requiring
be 13818 units and the quantity for ‘cutting in rock requiring
specialized research and development, such as new defence
blasting’ turned out to be 510 units as opposed to 3000
equipment, aircraft, etc. In such cases, neither off-the-shelf
units envisaged in the tender. The standard safeguard in
purchase nor sealed bidding may be appropriate. Even though
such a condition is to limit quantity variation. In this case
these solutions are appropriate under standard assumptions
also, a 25 per cent quantity variation limit clause was part
of bureaucratic oversight and monitoring, it is obvious that
of the contract but it included all the three items of
in the presence of weak or perverse incentives and ineffective
earthwork. In other words, only the gross variation in the
oversight even these standard prescriptions can fail through
total of the three items would have attracted that clause.
collusion. The supplier may be able to dump poor quality
and be able to exploit incompleteness of contracts, if the
CONCLUSION monitoring is weak, deterrents ineffective and collusion
possible. In the other problematic categories of customized
Public procurement has, of late, attracted some attention solutions and projects requiring research and development,
in the policy discussions on improving the governance, as the problems are even bigger. However, one of the primary
a prerequisite of increasing economic growth and, in imports of these recommendations is, standardization, which
particular, in improving the quality and efficiency of public can curb the extent of rents available for the public officials
services. On purely theoretical and a priori grounds, in this and the supplier to extract. Standardization of purchases
section, the public procurement situation has been analysed and detailing of projects leave less scope for manipulations
by bringing in the special characteristics of the services or later and increases effective competition. This should
items being procured and those of the public sector. Based improve, if not eliminate, the problems wherever it is feasible.
on notions of ‘incentive compatibility’ and the economics
of the same, we were led to certain expectations as regards Monitoring and Consumers’ Feedback, Independent
to types of failures and the reasons thereof. Even the small Audit, and Inspection
numbers of instances in the CAG reports illustrate the
points made in the a priori discussions. Some suggestions One approach to solving the problems of poor public services
which have been advanced by the multilateral agencies and and procurement is improving the incentive alignment of
others include: (a) procurement process based on project or public officials’ interest with that of the public. The other
product characteristics and (b) increasing the accountability is to hire another agent, who is given the task of monitoring
of the procurement agency, in particular, and the bureaucracy, the implementing agent. As long as the monitoring agent
in general. For the latter, transparency and disclosures are 26 These recommendations are for the four distinct stylized
a prerequisite. Also, monitoring by the end-users (public), categories of procurement.
Fiscal and Procurement Processes 103

has the right incentives and has the power over the hides more than it discloses. However once the right-to-
implementing agent, outcomes are likely to be better. Another information has been accepted, the quality of information
variation of this argument is that as long as there is conflict can always be improved over a period of time if there are
of interest between various agents, increasing their numbers incentives to monitor.
in decision-making makes collusion difficult. The While transparency and disclosures are necessary for
effectiveness of all of these arguments and proposals depends monitoring, they are no substitute for public awareness and
upon whether collusion between the supposedly independent consumer activism in curbing the perverse incentives of the
auditors and inspectors can be prevented. In case of internal public officials. There would not be significant changes
hierarchies, collusion is inevitable over a period of time if unless there is active involvement of civil society in the
external pressures by the principals (the public, in this public procurement and aggressive whistle-blowing against
context) are weak. Even in the case of independent external the poor quality of public services. There is a need for
agencies, payoffs and threats can be used to force them into stronger deterrents and punishments in case of erring public
collusion. Recent examples of corporate frauds in the US, officials and a need for basic changes in the legal framework.
wherein the ‘apparently’ independent auditors like Arthur As a first step, immunity to the public servants wherever
Andersen, with substantial reputation capital played ball in they are engaged in public service as opposed to enforcement,
connivance with insiders, point towards the limitations of needs to go. A separate judicial channel (courts) needs to
the effectiveness of such proposals. be established to try public officials as they can ride on the
Depending upon the extent, to which the pressures by clog created by the existing litigation. Class-action suits in
the public and the consumers can be brought to make both the context of public services should be admissible and
the implementing agency and the independent auditors and lawyers should be free to accept contingent fee contracts
inspectors accountable, the problems can be minimized. (currently, Bar Council prohibits such contracts). While all
The effects would be stronger if both the deterrents and the this sounds ambitious, the least that can be done by the
reputation payoffs are higher. Even though such a solution policy analysts is to factor in the poor outcomes of public
is likely to suffer from free-rider problem (individuals have procurement processes in new initiatives such as privatization
little incentive to monitor), exemplary compensation in and PFI.
case of damages can enhance incentives for monitoring and Meanwhile, there is an immediate need to remove policy-
induced distortions in the public procurement, which
whistle-blowing.
encourage inefficiencies. As discussed earlier, policies such
as price preferences to local manufacturers and suppliers,
Public Awareness, Transparency, Disclosures and Stronger
reservations for the small-scale enterprises, buying from
Deterrents
within the public sector (any anti-competitive procurement
The prerequisite for any kind of monitoring is complete for that matter) need to be changed. Similarly, the tendency
transparency and disclosure of all information related to to overcome budget constraints through costly procurements
public procurement. With the cost of information can be curbed easily. Even though there has been a trend
dissemination coming down dramatically, this would be a of decentralization of purchases, it probably needs to be
necessary (but not sufficient) condition to improve the taken further and agencies such as the Department of Supply
outcomes of public procurement. There would remain a and the Directorate of Quality Assurance, etc. need to be
tendency to reveal information in a manner in which it scaled down or wound up.

Box 4.2.1
E xpenditur
xpendituree R evie
Revie
evieww Commission on the D epar
Depar tment of SSupply
epartment upply and Affiliated O ffices
Offices

The Government of India recently reviewed the functions and activities of the Department of Supply in the Ministry of Commerce
and decided to abolish the department. It also disbanded the office of the Chief Controller of Accounts (CCA), wound up the Institute
of Supply and Quality Management and the shipping clearance work related to the office of the Directorate General of Supplies
and Disposals (DGS&D) and transferred the National Test House (NTH) to the Bureau of Indian Standards (BIS). All these offices
functioned under the Department of Supply in the Ministry of Commerce. Around the same time, the Expenditure Review
Commission reviewed the function of the Department of Supply and came up with its recommendations.

DEPARTMENT OF SUPPLY
The Department of Supply was expected to purchase and inspect the stores required for central government ministries and departments
and also for those state governments, autonomous bodies, public undertakings, etc., who wished to avail of its services. It was also
responsible for arranging payment to suppliers on behalf of the buying entities. Besides purchase and inspection, it was also entrusted
104 India Infrastructure Report 2003

with the responsibility of disposal and import of stores. It also ‘managed’ the cadres of the Indian Supply Service and the Ind ian
Inspection Service. The department performed these functions with the help of the offices of DGS&D and CCA and the facilities
of NTH.
Office of DGS&D
The office of DGS&D was established in 1951 for rendering procurement services to the central and state governments. The DGS&D
places rate contracts for common user items and through contracts against their ad hoc requirements. Even though ad hoc
procurements were decentralized in 1991, departments and agencies, which did not have procurement infrastructure, were allowed
to use DGS&D’s services for ad hoc procurements. In 1974, the Ministries of Defence, Railways, and Post and Telegraph were allowed
to procure items, exclusive to them, on their own. In 1984, the scientific departments were similarly exempted from the purview
of DGS&D for procurement. Besides procurement, the office of DGS&D was also entrusted by the departments with the disposal
of stores. This activity was wound up in 1999. (It had already been decentralized in 1985 for all civil departments).
Office of CCA
The main function of the office of CCA was to make payments to the suppliers for the procurement orders placed under rate contracts
of DGS&D. It also made payments to clearing agents for imports and raised bills for the consignees placing the order. The need
for the office of CCA was mainly due to the system of centralized payments to the suppliers.
NTH Facilities
NTH has facilities spread geographically for testing and evaluation of materials, products, equipment, etc. It was started in 1912
as a modest facility for evaluation of certain indigenous products for the Railways but had expanded to seven separate testing facilities
at six locations.

RECOMMENDATIONS OF THE EXPENDITURE REVIEW COMMISSION


The Expenditure Review Commission recommended drastic reduction in the overall strength of the Department of Supply and its
affiliate offices. Its recommendations, however, were preceded by the government decision to disband the department and the office
of CCA and also to transfer the NTH facility to BIS. The rationale behind some of the recommendations were:
Duplication of Testing Facilities
A study conducted by the Indian Institute of Managemetn (IIM), Kolkata, and completed in 1999, was cited by the commission.
The study pointed out that four central government-funded testing institutions, viz., BIS, Regional Testing Centers (RTCs), Pilot
Testing House (PTH) and NTH had similar capacities, equipment and facilities. This had led to excess capacities, wasteful duplication,
under-utilization, etc. The study recommended the integration of such facilities in order to avoid waste. The commission agreed
with the government decision to transfer the facilities to BIS and further recommended the examination of excess manning and
under-utilization once the facilities were integrated with that of BIS. It was pointed out that NTH facilities were able to generate
only 20 per cent of their non-plan expenditure as revenues and needed to market the facilities aggressively.
Decentralized Ad hoc Procurements and Payments
As the ad hoc procurements were decentralized in 1991 and even purchases for procurement through DGS&D’s rate contracts by
the state governments were decentralized in 1996, the payments made by the office of CCA during 1999–2000 had dropped to
about less than half of that made during 1995–6. With the recommendation that the payments be made by consignee departments,
the role of CCA itself was marginal and the commission recommended its abolition. Some of its residual functions were recommended
for absorption in the respective ministries at about 10 per cent of its original staff strength. With the decentralization of payments,
the commission noted that state governments and public-sector undertakings were directly placing orders (but using rate contract
prices) with the suppliers. Similarly, with decentralization and the winding up of disposal activities, DGS&D’s activities were confined
mainly to rate contract procurement. The ad hoc procurements, after decentralization in 1991, had collapsed, and during 1999–
2000 were barely about a tenth of that of 1991–2. Besides procurement, DGS&D carried out inspections through its Quality
Assurance wing. Some of the inspections carried out by this wing were being paid for by the suppliers. These inspections were for
orders directly placed on suppliers post-decentralization. The commission noted that this could create incentives for malpractice and
recommended stoppage of such inspections. Accordingly, the commission recommended downsizing of DGS&D by about one-third
and recommended the withering away of the cadres of Indian Supply Service and Indian Inspection Service. It noted that the activity
of DGS&D, since the abolition of centralized payment and ad hoc procurements, might be confined mostly to rate contracts for
common-user items.

SOME INTERESTING ISSUES


The report of the Expenditure Review Commission highlights a few interesting issues on the procurement system under the
Department of Supply and the way the government departments work. These are: (a) the basis for decentralizing or centralizing
procurement and inspections and (b) the presence of inertia and the self-serving character of cadres and departments.
Fiscal and Procurement Processes 105

Decentralization vs. Centralization of Procurement


The arguments for centralization of procurement, particularly that of standardized common-user items demanded repetitively, is that
it can enable the procurement agency to get quantity discounts as a bulk buyer. Even the commission notes the claim of savings
to the tune of Rs 145 crore in a year on just 12 items procured by DGS&D under rate contracts. However, getting the quantity
discounts when the payments are decentralized may not be as effective. On the other hand, if the quality of the procurement is
an issue in a centralized setting (possibly due to lack of incentive on the part of the procurement agency), then decentralizat ion
might improve the outcomes. No rationale has been given (or possibly even been considered) while recommending or taking decisio ns
affecting the procurement process on this dimension.
Self-serving Character of the Departments and Cadres
From the level of activities of DGS&D, CCA and NTH during the 1990s, it is evident that they are indeed coming down dramaticall y
with decentralization of procurement and inspection. In the case of NTH, it probably did not require IIM, Kolkata to figure out
that similar facilities were available with multiple agencies within the government and they were being under-utilized. However, just
three years before the study, DGS&D started work on a full-fledged institute known as the Institute of Supply and Quality
Management. The institute was supposed to be utilized for induction training of its cadres and other training programmes. Such
institutes can be found within any reasonably large cadre of the Government of India and, by that criterion, why not the cadres
of the Indian Supply Service and the Indian Inspection Service? Eventually, the government decided to close the institute just one
year after it became operational! Similarly, despite poor facility utilization and eventual transfer to BIS, the NTH, at the time of
writing of the report (2000), was constructing a new facility at Salt Lake in Kolkata at a cost of Rs 34.24 crores! Unless the information
was revealed to the government and the commission overnight, it is difficult to think how and on what ground such investments
were approved in the first place.

4.3 BUDGETARY PROCESSES AT THE STATE LEVEL

Shantanu Mitra • Vijay Pillai

The links between budgetary processes, public expenditure results of unconstrained market forces on the distribution of
outcomes, and infrastructure development within Indian income, wealth and other resources that might be considered
states are discussed herewith. While reference is made to socially unacceptable. On the other hand, political-economy
Orissa and Andhra Pradesh, the aim is to comment on the approaches, stress the role of political and institutional factors
situation of states in India in general. States differ on their in analysing and determining the role of the government.
fiscal details and also on the steps they have taken to institute Focus is laid on the implications of budgetary processes—
budgetary reforms. Nevertheless, the similarities, in terms by which is meant, broadly speaking, systems and procedures
of basic budgetary processes, fiscal positions and for budget formulation, budget execution, accounting,
administrative systems, are large enough to warrant general monitoring and audit. These greatly influence both the
applicability of this assessment. quantity and quality of public expenditure in key infrastructure-
States possess three broad types of policy instruments for related areas. Three aspects need to be considered: (1)
dealing with the supply of services for productive or supportive allocative efficiency: is the government making the ‘right’
functions: direct government provision (financing and/or investments? (2) technical efficiency and equity: is it making
delivery27), the use of taxes and subsidies to influence private them well and who benefits from such expenditure? and (3)
behaviour and regulation of private service providers. Drawing effectiveness: what are the impact and outcomes of such
on the principles of welfare economics, the case for state provision? As public policy-making and the budgeting
intervention is generally determined by the need to correct processes in states in India become stronger, they should
various forms of ‘market failure’ and to compensate for the start asking these questions. While a rigorous analysis of all
these issues is not possible at this juncture, an attempt has
The authors are Economic Advisers at the UK Department For been made to address them, wherever feasible.
International Development, India. This chapter does not necessarily
represent the views of DFID.
27 This is an important distinction. The question of who should INFRASTRUCTURE STATUS OF ORISSA AND ANDHRA
finance what relates largely to the public/private characteristics of the PRADESH
good or service, and the degree and nature of any externalities. The
question of who should deliver what (and how) is a separate issue The Eleventh Finance Commission (EFC) had
to be informed by criteria of cost-effectiveness and efficiency. commissioned a study of infrastructure resources across
106 India Infrastructure Report 2003

states. Setting its all-India average to 100, Orissa scored 81 FISCAL STATUS AND PUBLIC EXPENDITURE
overall, the fourth lowest among states, based on a score PATTERNS OF ORISSA AND ANDHRA PRADESH
of 77.2 for social and 81.7 for economic infrastructure.
Andhra Pradesh was higher than the all-India average overall, Orissa29
at 103.3. This was the result of a substantially above- Orissa is among the most fiscally distressed of all the major
average score for economic infrastructure (107.8) being states. As a poor and predominantly agrarian economy its own
offset by a relatively poor index value for social infrastructure tax take is low as a percentage of gross state domestic product
(79.3). (These scores are for 1995.) Similarly, the Centre (GSDP). But this is offset by high transfers from the
for Monitoring of the Indian Economy (CMIE) too has a Government of India which assure the state a higher than
Composite Development Index (CDI) for infrastructure average total revenue to GSDP ratio. At the same time, however,
for states in India. The index is based on the availability Orissa’s total expenditure ratio is the highest of all states,
of seven major infrastructural facilities, that is, energy, leading to high fiscal deficits and a spiralling debt burden.
transport, irrigation, finance, communication, education Table 4.3.1 summarizes the fiscal position of the state from
and health. With India’s CDI being taken as 100, Andhra 1995–6 onwards. The large spike in the fiscal deficits in 1998–
Pradesh has a CDI of 104 and Orissa of 101, placing them 9 and 1999–2000 was due primarily to the delayed and
at the 10th and 12th place respectively among the 15 major backdated implementation of the recommendations of the
states in India. Fifth Pay Commission. Since Orissa’s bureaucracy is by far the
Both indices indicate the poor relative position of both largest in relation to its population, the fiscal impact of this
Andhra Pradesh and Orissa when compared to the major pay award was greater on this state than on any other state.
states of India in terms of overall infrastructure Since then the state government has had some success
development28. They are cited here as contextual in reducing the deficit both due to higher revenues (both
background; no causal link is claimed between the analyses own revenue and central resources) and due to a degree of
that follow and these index scores since a comparative expenditure restraint. However, the fact that the state
assessment of budgetary systems in different states is not continues to run a significant primary deficit (deficit
offered. It must be recognized, moreover, that, irrespective excluding interest payments) indicates that further restraint
of the relative position of states according to these indices, of non-interest expenditure is required to bring down debt
the level of public infrastructure provision across India is levels and move the state towards fiscal sustainability.
deficient on almost all counts. The need, therefore, for Meanwhile, the high revenue deficit indicates that the state
increased infrastructural investment is obvious. How fiscal is continuing to borrow for recurrent expenditures that are
and budgetary reform can help to direct more resources, less likely to boost its debt-servicing capacity.
with greater efficacy, into priority infrastructural needs, is Table 4.3.2 confirms that the primary sources of
also discussed in this section. expenditure growth in recent years have been salaries,

Table 4.3.1
Orissa: A Fiscal Summary (as % of GSDP)

1995–6 1996–7 1997–8 1998–9 1999–2000 2000–1 2001–2


Actuals R.E.
Revenue 14.3 15.8 14.2 12.8 15.0 15.9 16.9
State’s own revenue 6.4 6.7 6.0 5.7 6.2 6.6 6.9
Central resources 7.8 9.1 8.2 7.0 8.8 9.3 10.0
Expenditure 19.3 22.4 19.7 22.3 24.5 23.6 24.3
of which interest payments 3.4 4.0 4.0 4.2 3.2 5.3 6.3
Gross fiscal surplus (+)/Deficit (–) –5.1 –6.6 –5.5 –9.6 –9.5 –7.7 –7.4
Primary deficit –1.6 –2.6 –1.5 –5.4 –6.4 –2.4 –1.1
Revenue deficit –2.9 –3.0 –2.7 –6.3 –6.5 –4.4 –4.4
Note: R.E. = Revised Estimate

28 Despite their poor relative position, both states have a higher 29 The section on Orissa draws heavily on data compiled by the
CMIE index than the national average due to the significantly lower World Bank. The authors are particularly grateful to V.J. Ravishankar,
scores of the bottom three states. U. Varma and M. Nagarajan of the New Delhi office of the World Bank.
Fiscal and Procurement Processes 107

Table 4.3.2
Orissa: Economic Composition of Expenditure i.e. by Economic/Object Head Classification (as % of GSDP)

1995–6 1996–7 1997–8 1998–9 1999–2000 2000–1 2001–2


Actuals R.E.
Interest 3.4 4.0 4.0 4.2 3.2 5.3 6.3
Salary 6.0 7.9 7.3 8.8 9.5 8.3 7.5
Grants-in-aid of salary 1.0 0.6 0.7 0.7 0.4 0.5 0.6
Pension 0.7 0.9 1.0 1.3 1.8 1.9 2.6
Major subsidy NA NA 0.4 0.3 0.4 0.3 0.2
Other revenue expenditure 6.0 5.5 3.6 3.8 6.3 4.1 4.2
Total non-interest revenue expenditure 17.2 18.9 16.9 19.1 21.5 20.4 21.3
Capital outlay 1.6 3.2 2.6 2.6 2.0 1.9 2.2
Net lending 0.5 0.3 0.1 0.7 1.0 1.3 0.9
Total expenditure + net lending 19.3 22.4 19.7 22.3 24.5 23.6 24.3
Note: R.E. = Revised Estimate

Table 4.3.3
Orissa: Sectoral Composition of Capital Outlays (as % of GSDP)

Capital Outlay 1995/6– 1998–9 1999–2000 2000-1 2001–2


1997/8 R.E. B.E.
Irrigation and flood control 56.1 66.8 66.8 52.0 58.4
Transport 21.3 14.4 16.5 14.5 20.6
Water supply, sanitation, housing, urban development 7.1 5.3 3.8 13.5 6.8
Power 6.6 7.0 1.4 1.3 1.0
Agriculture and allied activities 4.0 2.8 7.2 5.8 1.1
General services 1.6 1.9 1.9 4.6 3.4
Health and Family Welfare 1.5 0.6 0.7 3.4 5.4
Education, sports, art & culture 0.9 0.4 1.1 3.0 2.2
Welfare of SC, ST, OBC 0.4 0.3 0.3 1.2 0.8
Tourism, Investment in general, finance and trading 0.5 1.1 0.4 0.5 0.2
Industry and Minerals 0.1 –0.6 –0.1 0.2 0.1
Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
Note: B.E. = Budget Estimate; R.E. = Revised Estimate

pensions and a growing interest burden. The capital outlay accounted for by discretionary items, particularly non-salary
has been relatively stagnant over the period, whilst the O&M.
‘other revenue expenditure’ category, which includes all It would seem reasonable to draw a causal link between
non-salary Operational and Maintenance (O&M) fiscal distress and unrealistic revenue estimation, on the one
expenditure, has declined. Furthermore, it is apparent from hand, and stagnation and unpredictability of allocations for
Table 4.3.2 that Orissa’s budgeted revenue and expenditure capital expenditure and non-salary O&M on the other30.
estimates have been a poor guide to actual out-turns, both Such a process would, in turn, have negative consequences
in absolute terms and relative terms, to other states. A for infrastructure provision and utilization, both through
reasonable interpretation is that systematic overestimation less asset creation and through faster deterioration of existing
of revenue receipts has led to expenditures having to be
curtailed within the year. Both revenue and capital 30 In seeking to explain this suggested causality, political economy

expenditures, except in 1999–2000, have fallen short of approaches may be of most value. It is difficult, without recourse to
budget estimates. In general, and on average, however, capital such theories, to answer questions such as why there are incentives
to overspend on salaries, why historically there has been little concern
expenditures have tended to undershoot by the greater
about over-estimation of revenues, or why capital investment and
proportion. Given that salaries, pensions and interest are O&M have been treated as residuals. A full discussion of these issues
largely fixed and non-discretionary, it may be assumed that is beyond the scope of this section. (Norton and Elson, 2002, for
the shortfalls against budgeted revenue expenditure are a discussion of theory and applications.)
108 India Infrastructure Report 2003

Table 4.3.4
Andhra Pradesh: A Fiscal Summary (as % of GSDP)

1995–6 1996–7 1997–8 1998–9 1999–2000 2000–1 2001–2


Actuals B.E.
Revenue 11.5 11.6 13.6 12.0 13.0.0 13.3 13.8
State’s own revenue 6.3 6.4 8.5 8.1 8.6 8.8 8.7
Central resources 5.2 5.2 5.1 3.9 4.4 4.5 5.1
Expenditure 14.5 14.7 17.1 17.1 17.1 18.6 19.6
Revenue 12.5 12.6 14.4 14.4 14.0 16.0 16.3
Capital 2.1 2.1 2.7 2.7 3.1 2.6 3.3
Fiscal Surplus (+)/Deficit (–) –3.1 –3.1 –2.5 –5.0 –4.1 –5.3 –5.8
Primary deficit –1.2 –1.0 –0.3 –2.7 –1.5 –2.5 –2.5
Revenue deficit –0.9 –1.0 –0.7 –2.4 –1.0 –2.7 –2.5
Note: B.E. = Budget Estimate
Source: GoAP: Strategy Paper on Fiscal Reforms, 2001

Table 4.3.5
Andhra Pradesh: Economic Composition of Expenditure i.e. by Economic/Object Head Classification (as % of GSDP)

1995–6 1996–7 1997–8 1998–9 1999–2000 2000–1


Actuals B.E.
Interest 2.0 2.2 2.4 2.5 2.8 3.1
Salary 5.2 5.3 5.6 5.2 6.0 6.3
Pension 1.2 1.2 1.3 1.3 1.6 1.7
Non-salary O&M 1.1 1.1 1.4 1.5 1.9 1.8
Transfers and Subsidies 3.7 3.5 3.5 4.2 3.6 5.1
Other Revenue Expenditure 0.1 0.2 0.4 0.8 0.8 0.5
Total Revenue Expenditure 13.4 13.5 14.6 15.5 16.7 18.4
Total Capital Expenditure 2.2 2.2 2.9 2.9 2.9 3.6
Net lending 0.8 1.0 1.7 1.6 0.7 0.9
Total expenditure 15.6 15.7 17.6 18.4 19.6 22.0

assets. Additionally, less spending on complementary inputs economic growth—in other words, where there is a strong
for service delivery (such as medicines and schoolbooks) case for the state to play a leading role.
would have reduced their utilization. These trends need to Attention needs to be paid to the effectiveness and
be set in the context of historically high capital expenditure efficiency of public spending, as much as to levels of
(in relation to GSDP, the highest of all major states from expenditure. In Orissa, inefficiencies and leakages in the
1991–2 to 1996–7). The squeezing of non-salary O&M is prioritization, design and management of capital projects
undoubtedly a concern; there is ample anecdotal evidence appear to be large32.
of inadequate allocations for maintenance of existing
infrastructure. Andhra Pradesh
The sectoral composition of capital expenditure (Table
The average annual growth rate of Andhra Pradesh during
4.3.3) appears to be broadly appropriate. The lion’s share
the 1990s was 5.3 per cent, almost a full percentage point
of capital spending goes on irrigation (including flood
lower than the national average of 6.2 per cent. During the
control) and transport, both examples of investments having
five-year period ending 1999–2000 there have been large
significant public-good characteristics31 and crucial for
31 This is not to deny that substantial scope exists for increased 32 World Bank research suggests, for example, that the efficiency
cost recovery, particularly in irrigation which has both public and of expenditure on irrigation has been low. Analysis of a major Bank-
private-good characteristics depending on the type of irrigation system financed irrigation project indicates that delays and other deficiencies
and the ease with which private or community property rights can in implementation have resulted in an economic rate of return (ERR)
be effectively enforced at different stages of the delivery system. of only 6 per cent, compared with 14 per cent at appraisal.
Fiscal and Procurement Processes 109

Table 4.3.6
Andhra Pradesh: Sectoral Composition of Capital Outlays (as % of GSDP)

Capital Outlay 1996–7 1997–8 1998–9 1999–2000 2000–1


R.E. B.E.
General Services 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.04
Education 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.00
Health 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.22 0.37
Welfare Programmes 0.06 0.05 0.1 0.2 0.05
Agriculture 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.01 0.01
Irrigation 0.75 0.83 0.76 0.92 0.93
Power 0.0 0.04 0.02 0.03 0.02
Transport 0.23 0.11 0.25 0.33 0.59

variations in the agricultural and industrial growth rates, by the fact that power subsidies are almost twice as large
while a much more consistent performance was seen in the as government expenditure in primary health.
services sector. Thus, growth rates in agriculture ranged Rising debt burdens and consequent interest repayments
between (–)15.3 per cent and (+) 24.3 per cent; while that squeeze out the resources deployed for infrastructure and
of the industrial sector was between (+) 1.8 per cent and other development priorities. What is the state borrowing
(+) 7.8 per cent. Andhra Pradesh had a per capita income for? While in recent years Andhra Pradesh has succeeded
of Rs 10,886 in 2000–1 (in 1993–4 prices), a little lower in reducing its revenue deficit (borrowing for recurrent
than the national figure of Rs 11,799. expenditures), it still continues to be high (see Table 4.3.5)—
Relative to many other states, Andhra Pradesh had a better indicating that much of this borrowing does not go towards
record in fiscal management until about 1998–9. The fiscal generating future income streams for the state.
deficit was about 2.5 per cent of GSDP in 1997–8 and Andhra Pradesh has shown a relatively good performance
almost doubled to 5 per cent the following year—as in Orissa compared to some other states, in terms of increasing trends
the civil service pay award contributed much to this sharp in both capital allocations and those for non-salary O&M.
deterioration. Table 4.3.4 summarizes the fiscal situation in While this is a positive development, given the historical
Andhra Pradesh. The state’s own revenue performance has under-funding in the infrastructure sector there is a need
improved during the last five years and its share in total to continue this positive trend in budget allocations for
revenues rose from 62 per cent in 1997–8 to 66 per cent in infrastructure, and equally importantly, the efficiency and
2000–1. At the same time, there has been a decline in the efficacy with which assets are created and utilized.
share of central transfers to Andhra Pradesh—declining from As in Orissa, irrigation and transport take up a large
5.2 per cent of GSDP in 1995–6 to 3.9 per cent in 1998– proportion of public expenditure where the state rightly
9 and then improving to 4.5 per cent in 2000–1. plays a leading role. But there is also a critical need to step
The revenue expenditure33, which was stable for the up capital expenditures in the health and education sectors
three-year period ending 1999–2000 at 14.3 per cent of (see Table 4.3.6).
GSDP increased to 16 per cent in 2000–1, mainly due to
the reflection of explicit power subsidy in the budget. Capital
expenditure has shown a steady increase in recent years— BUDGETARY PROCESSES34
from 2.1 per cent in 1995–6 to 3.1 per cent in 1999–2000. The objectives of the budget process (or public expenditure
Salaries, pensions and interest payments make up about 64 management (PEM) system) may be summarized as:
per cent of the total revenue expenditure of the state.
Subsidies (for example, in the power sector) make a significant 1. to maintain fiscal discipline by ensuring that aggregate
share of public expenditure—and much of it is untargeted. expenditure is kept within limits dictated by revenue capacity
That subsidies continue to be a huge drain on public resources and sustainable levels of borrowing;
leading to distortion of spending priorities is exemplified
34 This sub-section draws upon various unpublished reports
33 In India government expenditure is clubbed into capital and prepared by Bannock Consulting and JPS Associates for the
revenue expenditure. Capital expenditure typically consists of capital Government of Orissa, and on the Government of Orissa’s own
outlays for building new assets and loans given by the state for various internal policy paper on Budget Reforms and Public Expenditure
purposes. Revenue expenditures are the running costs of the government Management. The section also uses findings of a series of unpublished
and includes recurrent expenditures on various programmes or schemes, Impact and Expenditure Reviews conducted by Government of Andhra
and expenditure on interest, salariess and any subsidies. Pradesh for eight departments in 2001, with assistance from DFID.
110 India Infrastructure Report 2003

Table 4.3.7
Orissa and Andhra Pradesh: Deviation of Final Accounts from Budget Estimates (percentage variation, Accounts/Budget Estimate)

1995–6 1996–7 1997–8 1998–9 1999–2000


Revenue Orissa –5.7 –9.8 –10.6 –19.7 –5.0
Receipts Andhra Pradesh –2.9 –2.3 10.3 –8.8 –9.6
All states 0.3 0.5 –3.3 –13.1 –5.9
Revenue Orissa –8.2 –7.7 –9.6 –6.0 4.9
Expenditure Andhra Pradesh –2.5 19.4 5.9 4.4 –10.5
All states –1.0 3.1 –2.6 –4.1 0.1
Capital Orissa –17.3 –11.6 –7.7 –4.5 –25.8
Expenditure Andhra Pradesh 31.2 –27.2 24.1 51.5 31.1
All states –0.1 –3.3 4.8 2.0 4.9
Source: RBI

2. to promote prioritization by ensuring that available with regard to certain transfers from the centre, which form
resources are allocated in line with the government’s strategic a significant proportion of the revenues of the states. Arguably
objectives and/or ‘rational’ social and economic criteria; the real systemic problem lies deeper, in the perceived need
3. to deliver value for money by ensuring that to show a rising Plan budget (which is equated politically
resources are used efficiently and effectively in the pursuit with ‘desirable’ investment to enhance productive capacity).
of priorities. Similarly, the practice of incremental budgeting for major
non-Plan expenditures, particularly salaries (reasons for which
Additionally, the processes have to be such as to ensure
have also been, at root, political) contributes to the problem.
accountability and transparancy at each stage. Whilst these
The resultant upward pressures on expenditure bids have
are important in helping to deliver the three objectives set
led to budgeted revenue receipts being fixed at levels inflated
out above, they are also important in their own right to
by the need to justify excessive expenditure levels rather
safeguard the integrity and legitimacy of the system.
than by actual revenue realization potential.
It is essential to consider any PEM system within its
In these circumstances it is hardly surprising that the
institutional context, that is, as a system of formal laws,
result has been ad hoc cash rationing within the year in
rules and processes, as well as informal customs and incentives
response to revenue shortfalls. And since non-discretionary
that help determine how the system actually operates and
items such as salaries and debt service effectively have first
how effectively it meets the objectives outlined earlier. To
call on resources, such rationing has been reflected
facilitate the description and the appraisal of the key features
particularly in the delayed implementation of investment
of the system in the Indian states, the analysis35 has been
projects and postponement of non-wage O&M (including
broken down among the three component parts of the
maintenance of infrastructure assets).
budgetary cycle: (i) strategic planning and budget
formulation; (ii) budget execution; (iii) audit and evaluation.
Dual Budgeting Dysfunctionality
The effects of the dual budgeting system (separation between
STRATEGIC PLANNING AND BUDGET FORMULATION Plan and non-Plan budgets) in the Indian context have been
Unrealistic Revenue Forecasts well documented. Although the separate focus on Plan
expenditure in theory ensures that development activities
Unrealistic revenue forecasting would appear to have been are given due weight, as already noted, this produces
a major contributor to the lack of fiscal discipline, which, incentives to budget for an inexorably rising Plan even when
as mentioned before, has led to capital and maintenance this is clearly not feasible. Greater emphasis is given to the
expenditures being squeezed. Unpredictability also arises budgeted Plan allocation than to its realization36. More
fundamentally, because the two budgets are prepared
35 What follows is not intended to be a detailed and exhaustive
description of all aspects of the system. It is rather an attempt to
36 Moreover, as is widely understood, the rule-of-thumb that Plan
identify some of the key features contributing to particular observed
outcomes in Orissa and Andhra Pradesh, especially those most relevant expenditures comprise of 70 per cent capital and 30 per cent recurrent
to public infrastructure development. It highlights only areas where spending no longer holds: as reported by the Reserve Bank of India
improvement is required; this is not to say that the current system (RBI) report on State Finances (2001–2) recurrent items account for
does not also have its strengths. more than 50 per cent of Plan expenditures aggregated across all states.
Fiscal and Procurement Processes 111

separately with little coordination between these processes The prioritization process for Plan expenditure tends to
or between the Finance and Planning Departments, there be subjective rather than being carefully derived from policy
is really no means of focusing on total sector costs and little objectives. In practice, the process is highly centralized and
or no incentive for spending departments to trade off between ‘top-down’, with the budgets for most expenditures relating
Plan and non-Plan expenditures. States have a tendency to to local functions, such as education and health, being
maximize the amount of Plan funds available from the decided at the state level. Although District Plans provide
centre by overestimating their balance on current revenues. indications of the Districts’ views on priorities and phasing,
Since all Plan programmes become part of revenue these are typically only advisory to spending departments
expenditure after completion of the Plan period, the pressures when preparing their detailed budgets37. At the level of
that work towards increase in Plan spending also contribute individual projects, whilst cost-benefit analysis is theoretically
to the increase in expenditure on the non-Plan account. mandatory, in practice it is not always prepared, or is sketchy,
Clearly the sanctity attached to maximizing the Plan size and seldom reviewed.
has led to some detrimental outcomes. Formulation of non-Plan budgets is similarly devoid of
any effective medium-term perspective. Limited discretion
Supplementary Budgets is given to spending departments, with the Finance
Department issuing prescriptions on budgeting of specific
The legality that permits the processing of supplementary
line items according to extremely detailed classifications.
budgets three times a year has led to governments viewing
Combined with limited virement (‘re-appropriation’)
the initial budget as a soft constraint. As shown in Table
authority, this leads to over-centralization because there is
4.3.7, a result of this soft initial constraint has been in terms
always informational asymmetry between the Finance
of poor ‘fiscal marksmanship’—deviation between actual
Department and the spending departments with regard to
figures and BE figures for the year.
the appropriate allocation and management of sector budgets.
The approach taken is one of incrementalism, as noted
Incomplete Budgets
earlier, with little discrimination between the needs of
These deleterious effects are exacerbated by the fact that the different departments and programmes.
budget is not comprehensive. The existence of various extra-
budgetary flows (for example, in-kind flows to districts, No Outcome Measures
funding from externally-aided projects to state/district
Strategic prioritization has suffered further from the lack of
societies) further vitiates attempts to focus on sector costs
any linkage between expenditure allocations and ‘outcome’
or allocations in a comprehensive manner. In addition,
measures (such as higher agricultural incomes, improved
contingent liabilities (for example, in respect of guarantees
health status of the population, etc.). This prohibits any
to public enterprises, power purchase agreements and investor
meaningful attempt to prioritize between competing
letters of comfort) are not subject to adequate scrutiny of
demands in terms of policy objectives or to measure the
the Finance Department, or to prudent overall ceilings, and
performance of spending departments in achieving the same.
are not fully reflected in the budget.
Deficiencies in Process
Lack of Medium-term Perspective
Both Plan and non-Plan budget formulation are largely
There are also important flaws in the planning process itself.
manual processes. Only in the final stages prior to publication
Perhaps the most pernicious of these is the lack of any effective
is there any attempt to use computational and planning
medium-term perspective for programming Plan expenditure.
tools. This process involves huge effort and makes it
Whilst a Five Year Plan exists on paper, the lack of realism
practically impossible to manipulate data and to test the
in macro-budgeting renders this increasingly less related to
impact of different scenarios and options. Lack of
annual plans. There seems to be a disconnect between priorities
computerization of the budget process, therefore, represents
set out in the Plans and actual public expenditure allocations
an important technological constraint to improving
in the annual budgets. No formal mechanisms exist for regularly
budgeting practice.
reviewing or rolling over the Five Year Plan. The lack of
Last, but not least, very little public consultation takes
effective medium-term expenditure programming is
place at state level as part of this process. Recognizing that
exacerbated by the fact that at the time of Plan preparation
there is no assessment of the eventual non-Plan liability 37 Whilst this is the case for most states, Kerala, for example, has
resulting from the forward O&M cost implications of plan moved substantially towards devolving untied allocations to districts,
projects. Such tendencies can lead to the creation of assets to be allocated according to local needs based upon participatory
without the means to utilize and maintain them. planning techniques.
112 India Infrastructure Report 2003

the allocation of public resources is essentially a political do not agree, so there is no common basis for dialogue in
rather than a purely technocratic exercise, formal consultation the event of problems.
with citizens or representative civil society groups can be an
important conduit for promoting transparency and ensuring ‘Public Accounts’
that the voices of the intended beneficiaries of public
A lack of timely fund release by the Finance Department,
expenditure are heard38.
and the fact that unspent appropriations may not be carried
over, have led to the common practice among departments
BUDGET EXECUTION, ACCOUNTING, AND of establishing ‘Civil Deposit Accounts’/‘Public Accounts’
MONITORING to which expenditures can be booked even though no
expenditure has actually been incurred39. By decentralizing
Given the problems and weaknesses in the budget cash balances and removing expenditure from effective
formulation process outlined above, the extent to which it scrutiny, this practice weakens accountability and financial
is meaningful to talk of effective execution of such budgets control, further inflating the reported fiscal deficit, and the
is debatable. It is virtually predetermined, for example, that Government’s already-high borrowings.
there will be substantial variations from budgeted receipts The weaknesses outlined above amount to a sure recipe
and expenditures, which is reflected in the widespread and for ineffective expenditure control and poor implementation
regular use of Supplementary Budgets within the year. of agreed budgets. The present budget controls have not
Equally important, there are serious problems with the been wholly effective in ensuring that voted expenditure is
budget execution process itself, which contribute separately spent on agreed activities as allocated, or in preventing
to sub-optimal budgetary outcomes. departments from exceeding their cash limits, contributing
significantly to high budget deficits and chronic cash flow
Accounting System Weaknesses difficulties. Liquidity problems, along with the lack of any
cash planning system, result in cash rationing by departments,
Many of the problems arise from the fact that accounting
leading to expenditure being re-prioritized within the year
systems are largely manual. As a result the flow of data is
in an ad hoc manner.
fragmented, untimely and inflexible in terms of the depth
of analysis available. Accountability in budget imple-
Weak Project Management
mentation is seriously undermined.
After processing of transactions by local treasuries, For infrastructure development, the effectiveness of capital
accounting information is prepared and passed to the expenditure management is crucial. As already mentioned,
Accountant General, where it is summarized and the returns weak project appraisal practices at the outset, lead to
forwarded to the Finance Department for budgetary control inefficiencies in the allocation of capital expenditure. Once
purposes. The time-consuming nature of these manual approved and included in the Plan, weak project management
processes means that this data is usually two months old by procedures mean that many individual projects are not
the time it reaches the Finance Department, by which time effectively managed to ensure timely achievement of clear
the problems have often got worse. Where sub-treasuries and measurable outputs. It appears that too many projects
exist, they can further add to the delay. In addition, accounts are allowed to continue well beyond the point at which they
are not reconciled on a regular basis, with the result that should have been completed, or when it is clear that they
in-year financial information is hardly reliable. are no longer cost-effective. Combined with political
Budgetary discipline is further weakened by the fact that incentives to announce new schemes and continually raise
the treasuries are unable to check availability of budget the overall Plan size, the result is an excessive number of
provision at the point of payment, and by the level of projects, many of them starved of resources with little
aggregation of accounting data supplied to the Finance prospect of timely completion. Simultaneously, weak
Department. Since these data are at the overall budget-head financial controls allow for overspending on individual
level, in the event of an overspend it is not always possible projects, and the possibility of misappropriation of funds
to see which department has caused it. An additional problem ‘earmarked’ for specific purposes.
is the lack of correspondence between alternative sources of Weak and opaque procurement procedures, and unclear
data. Local departmental records and central records often client and contractor roles and relationships, are also major
factors leading to inefficiency, corruption and poor value
38 See Norton and Elson (2002) for examples and a summary of
international experience with participatory budgeting initiatives. The
pending ‘Freedom of Information’ bills in many states could usefully 39See Section 6.4 for more details on this and other accounting
incorporate clauses providing for such consultation. anomalies.
Fiscal and Procurement Processes 113

for money in infrastructure spending. In summary, it is including some with major infrastructure budgets such as
apparent that poor capital expenditure controls undermine Public Works, Water Resources and Rural Development, do
both fiscal discipline and value-for-money objectives of not have internal auditors appointed by the Finance
public expenditure management. Department. Instead they have total control over their own
internal audit. More generally, internal audit staff report
only to the head of the department concerned and not to
AUDIT AND EVALUATION
the Finance Department or any other organization. Because
External Audit the auditors have no power to enforce compliance to audit
objections, compliance to internal audit reports is very low
The external audit function, which belongs to the and action is rarely taken on the basis of audit reports,
Comptroller and Auditor General (CAG) of India, appears except when procedural deviations are pointed out.
to be effective in identifying many of the most serious As noted above, targets are rarely set for development
weaknesses and inefficiencies at the state level. Reports from ‘outcomes’ to be achieved, so there is little means of checking
CAG are regularly tabled in the state legislature. The impact the effectiveness of expenditure in delivering policy objectives.
of this external audit, however, depends crucially on the Although physical targets are set in respect of Plan schemes,
effectiveness and timeliness with which the Public Accounts these are in the nature of intermediate outputs rather than
Committee reviews CAG reports and the effectiveness of social outcomes. Moreover, resource shortfalls that arise
mechanisms for follow-up and enforcement, including the almost as soon as the Plan is produced make it practically
use of disciplinary powers40. impossible to hold spending departments accountable for
planned physical achievements. Although the efficiency audit
Internal Audit department carries out some reviews of project performance,
In Orissa the internal audit function consists of common very little attention is paid to the effectiveness of non-plan
cadre audit (which audits the accounts of the central expenditure. (And efficiency audit is subject to the same
administrative departments of the government), local fund problems of weak capacity and low compliance as the rest
audit (which focuses on institutions such as block of internal audit.) In general, there appears to be a lack of
development offices, gram panchayats, municipal systematic and comprehensive review of the extent to which
corporations and grant-aided educational institutions) and expenditure represents value-for-money and contributes to
efficiency audit (which is concerned with the efficiency with higher-level policy objectives.
which resources are deployed by administrative departments).
Internal audit is not generally effective at present. It is
REFORM DIRECTIONS
highly transaction-based. It does not focus on the underlying
system weaknesses, correction of which could have helped It is evident that the budget process at state level suffers
management in developing more cost-effective controls. Its from multiple weaknesses. There is lack of clarity,
scope is mainly to restricted voucher audit, which involves predictability, transparency, accountability and comprehen-
checking whether expenditure is as per sanction, properly siveness at various stages of the budget cycle. The result is
authorized and supported by sufficient proof of payment poor outcomes with regard to fiscal discipline, strategic
as per rules and law. It does not include checking whether prioritization and value-for-money. What, then, should be
the expenditure has been utilized for the intended purposes; the priorities for reform of PEM at state level? A number
there is no physical verification of civil works or assets. of broad strands are suggested by the above analysis.
Audit planning, techniques and reporting are weak and
outdated, and exacerbated by weak staff capacity. There are
Need for MTEFs
serious staff shortages in all areas of internal audit and audits
of institutions are typically in arrears by five to ten years, In terms of planning and budget formulation, the overall
although this problem is also due to poor planning and imperative is to move towards instituting a comprehensive
outdated methods for selecting and carrying out audits. medium-term approach to expenditure programming. Such
There are more fundamental reasons for the ineffectiveness approaches, being operationalized in an increasing number
of internal audit. Independence and accountability are weak. of countries in the form of Medium-Term Expenditure
A significant number of the administrative departments, Frameworks (MTEFs), involve programming expenditure
(i) on a multi-year (usually 3–5 years) basis allowing for
40 For a brief review of the CAG audit, see Chapter 5.4 ‘Office forward planning; (ii) in the context of a realistic and
of the CAG of India as Accountability in Government,’ by Ajay sustainable macro-fiscal framework; (iii) with reference to
Pandey in this report. a coherent set of policy objectives and sector strategies,
114 India Infrastructure Report 2003

strengthening the link between inputs and outputs; and (iv) Audit Reform Priorities
taking an integrated approach to capital, current and
Major improvements are required to enable internal audit
externally-aided resources, so that the appropriate capital-
to play its proper role in the accountability process. These
current mix can be achieved and the recurrent cost
include organizational and management changes,
implications of capital expenditure taken into account. The
strengthening of audit planning and skills, focus on
role of the Finance Department in such a process would be
underlying systems rather than merely transactions, and
limited to specifying and monitoring strategic expenditure
more effective reporting and compliance mechanisms.
aggregates and agreeing to the strategic outcomes to be Ultimately, there must be the willingness and the procedures
achieved, leaving spending departments with flexibility to to hold controlling officers accountable for mismanagement
determine the details. However, the formulation and and malfeasance.
institutionalization of a fully-fledged MTEF takes time to
achieve, and in the context of the Indian states an incremental
Political and Administrative Commitments
approach, putting in place the most fundamental elements
first, is likely to be the more sustainable and realistic way It would be a major mistake to treat PEM reforms as a
forward41. technocratic exercise. Constructive political engagement is
critical in bringing about the positive changes desired. Since
Importance of Computerization the budget is, in essence, a tool for translating political
intention into public policy, involvement of the Cabinet
Moreover, it must be recognized that introduction of and the Legislature in the budget process is essential,
medium-term expenditure planning without attention to particularly in budget formulation and in ensuring
budget execution and expenditure control will not lead to compliance with external audit. More generally, as noted,
the desired objectives. Addressing these problems will require serious efforts to promote wider stakeholder-participation
computerization of accounting processes to provide high and citizen-focus in the budget process can be a powerful
quality and more timely information, along with improved tool for increasing transparency, holding governments to
and streamlined systems to enable the Finance Department account and improving the impact of budgets.
to utilize this data to better control expenditure and manage
the cash flow. It is important to open up access to
computerized data to departments other than Finance and DEVELOPMENT OF REFORMS IN ORISSA AND
the Accountant General in order to promote more integrated ANDHRA PRADESH
data use and ensure a common basis for dialogue between
the Finance and other departments in the event of The need to institute a wide-ranging programme of reforms
to address the weaknesses in the existing budgetary process has
disagreements or problems. Although computerization of
been acknowledged by the Governments of both Orissa and
accounting is the first priority, computerization of transaction
Andhra Pradesh. A number of important steps have already
processing—such as payroll transactions—will also be
been taken and others are ongoing. Following is a snapshot
important in improving expenditure control.
of progress as of August 2002. It should be stressed that this
is very much a work in progress. Whilst much remains to be
Capital Expenditure Management done in terms of implementation, the following initiatives
Strengthening of capital expenditure controls, including indicate the seriousness of intent of both governments.
procurement procedures, is of particular importance to
infrastructure development. This should cover all key stages MTFP Agreed with the Government of India
of the project cycle, including feasibility, design, tendering, As a critical underpinning of any future move to medium-
monitoring and evaluation, with appropriate approval term expenditure programming, both governments have
procedures, wherever relevant. At the same time, improved articulated a clear medium-term fiscal framework designed
project and programme management procedures, with clear to restore overall fiscal sustainability and setting out its
reporting and monitoring arrangements, are required to overall fiscal targets over a five-year period. This is enshrined
improve the performance of individual projects and the in a Medium-Term Fiscal Plan (MTFP) agreed with the
capital programme as a whole. Government of India, and in a highly candid Cabinet-
approved White Paper/Strategy Paper, which sets out the
41 It is noteworthy that some states are looking at the national rationale for, and elements of, fiscal reform. The latter
debate on Fiscal Responsibility Act (FRA), which is intended to give represents an important mechanism for political engagement
legal backing to medium-term fiscal forecasting. in respect of a politically difficult set of reforms.
Fiscal and Procurement Processes 115

Careful Reviews of Expenditure Priorities concurrence of the CAG, and will require modification
across all states of India, the Government of Andhra Pradesh
A zero-based public investment review has been initiated by
is planning to simplify the classification as a supplementary
the Government of Orissa, led by a high-level review
to the existing classification.
committee, chaired by the Chief Secretary. The Government
of Andhra Pradesh conducted a similar ‘Zero-Based Budget
Computerization on Pilot Basis
Review’ in 2001. The aim of these exercises was not to cut
investment spending, but to improve its efficiency and Computerization of the treasuries is underway on a pilot
effectiveness by reallocating Plan resources from low-priority basis, with financial assistance from the Government of
to high-priority projects or schemes and ensuring adequate India. As noted, this will be essential to improve the timeliness
fund availability for the prioritized schemes. The zero-based and the reliability of accounting information for budgetary
review is a one-time exercise, to be followed by improvements control purposes.
in procedures and capacity for programming, evaluation The Government of Andhra Pradesh has plans of moving
and funding of the investment budget. from a system of cash accounting to modified accrual
In Orissa, the main item of non-Plan expenditure, namely accounting initially on a proforma basis.
staff costs, is similarly being subjected to fundamental review
through a process of organizational reviews of all major Cash Management Plan
departments. The objective of this exercise, initiated in July Another extremely important initiative of both the
2002, is to review the appropriate role and functions of Governments of Orissa and of Andhra Pradesh, particularly
departments, the organizational structure and staff strength in view of the liquidity crisis facing the states, is the
required to fulfil these functions, as well as to advise on preparation of a detailed cash-management plan. The overall
procedures, management systems and mechanisms for objective is to enable the governments to more proactively
enhancing client focus. Thus, whilst these reviews are seen manage their cash flows, in order to provide more
as a critical step towards the government’s stated aim of predictability in budget execution and avoid the ad hoc cash
reducing the size of the civil service, they have a considerably rationing which has prevailed thus far.
broader focus on effectiveness and performance. As with
the zero-based investment review, they are a one-time exercise. Audit, Evaluation, and Transparency
In Andhra Pradesh, the effort is currently on preparing
MTEFs for a few sectors on a pilot basis, which will help Both states have undertaken a review of their internal audit
take forward medium-term expenditure planning to the function, and plan to initiate a programme to strengthen
level of spending departments. In addition, the Government the same in due course. Meanwhile, they are implementing,
of Andhra Pradesh has taken the initiative of holding public or designing a range of measures to increase transparency
consultations to feed into the budget-making process. and accountability to the client or end-user of public services.
These include: (i) passage of a Freedom of Information Act;
More Flexibility for Spending Departments (ii) consideration of ‘citizen’s charter’-type mechanisms to
inform service users of their entitlements and provide
In Andhra Pradesh, the sectoral budget ceilings are now grievance redressal procedures; and (iii) plans to carry out
being set at the start of the budget process and departments expenditure-tracking studies of some key public services, in
are being given enhanced planning and financial powers. order to ascertain the extent to which expenditure reaches
The spending departments would be held responsible for the intended end-user and the extent of leakage/inefficiency
payments, accounting and accountability. The system of at each level in the system.
control exercised by the Finance Department is moving The Government of Andhra Pradesh is moving towards
away from micro-management, to the selection of an ‘anchor’ greater performance orientation, under which each
for each department, for example, limits on running costs, department has prepared a set of performance indicators,
and such an ‘anchor’ would then provide the basis for which can be monitored with current or prospective data
improved dialogue between the Finance and other availability. These indicators would provide the basis for
departments. making quarterly budgetary releases, and also for feeding
It has also taken some initial steps to bundle heads of into budget discussions for the subsequent year.
account and give greater flexibility to departments. The Work is being planned or is under consideration in both
present system of seven-digit classification remains too states, with cooperation from the World Bank and the
detailed and inconsistent with the principle for permitting Department for International Development (DFID), to use
greater flexibility in budget management. While the formal diagnostic tools like State Financial Accountability Assessment
revision of the budgetary classification requires the (SFAA) and Procurement Assessment Review to identify the
116 India Infrastructure Report 2003

problems in the financial accountability and procurement systems but the pace of such reforms is likely to be slower;
systems and prepare action plans to tackle them. (ii) governments must lead PEM reforms, with the key
central ministries playing a strong leadership role. External
CONCLUSION agencies (such as the World Bank and DFID) can at best
play a supporting and advisory role. Not all key players in
PEM reform is not an agenda for developing countries the government (executive, legislature, the Ministry of
alone. Many developed countries also have some way to go Finance, CAG and the main spending departments) may
in this regard. But given the urgency in meeting the growth, have the same degree of commitment to reforms; (iii) it is
infrastructural development and poverty-reduction objectives important not to underestimate the complexity of the PEM
for developing countries, the criticality of these reforms system and the significance of the interlinkages between its
becomes that much greater. different elements. The system is only as strong as its weakest
International experience offers some important lessons link—priority should therefore be given to tackling the
that may be of value to Indian states pursuing PEM reforms, most fundamental weaknesses first, whilst keeping in view
or to those attempting to understand or support the process the system as a whole and adjusting priorities over time as
from the outside. In general, there are no blueprint solutions, appropriate; (iv) it is important to focus on where the real
and it is important to bear in mind five sets of issues: (i) problems lie—good diagnosis is important and it should
the pace of reforms is likely to be more rapid when look for the underlying institutional and political, as well
governments are forced to take action by a macroeconomic as technical issues; and, (v) one should be prepared for the
or fiscal crisis. In the absence of crises, pressures for long haul—PEM reforms cannot be instituted overnight
improvements may still build up in under-performing and momentum must be sustained over the medium-term.

REFERENCES

Anand, Mukesh, Amaresh Bagchi, and Tapas K. Sen (2002), ‘Fiscal DFID Understanding and Reforming Public Expenditure
Discipline at the State Level: Perverse Incentives and Paths Management, (2001), Department for International
to Reform’, Discussion Paper No.1, New Delhi: National Development
Institute of Public Finance and Policy. Dillinger, William and Steven Webb (1999a), ‘Fiscal Management
Bajari, P. and S. Tadelis (2001), ‘Incentives versus Transaction in Federal Democracies: Argentina and Brazil’, Policy Research
Costs: A Theory of Procurement Contracts’, Rand Journal of Working Paper No. 2121, Washington D.C.: World Bank.
Economics, Vol. 32, pp. 387–407. ———(1999b), ‘Decentralization and Fiscal Management in
Banerjee, A. and E. Duflo (2000), ‘Reputation Effects and the Colombia’, Policy Research Working Paper No. 2122,
Limits of Contracting: A Study of the Indian Software Washington D.C.: World Bank.
Industry’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 115, pp. 989– Giugale, Marcelo, Adam Korobow, and Steven Webb (1999), ‘A
1017. New Model for Market-Based Regulation of Subnational
Bird, Richard (2000), ‘Transfers and Incentives in Intergovernmental Borrowing: The Mexican Approach’, Policy Research Working
Fiscal Relations’, in S.J. Burki and G. Perry (eds), Paper No. 2370, p.3, Washington D.C.: World Bank.
Decentralization and Accountability of the Public Sector, p. Government of Andhra Pradesh, (2001), Strategy Paper on Fiscal
121, Annual World Bank Conference on Development in Reforms.
Latin America and the Caribbean, Washington D.C.: World Government of India (2000), Report of the Eleventh Finance
Bank. Commission on the Additional Terms of Reference, Ministry of
Bos, D. and M. Kolmar (2000), ‘Self-Correcting Mechanisms in Finance, New Delhi.
Public Procurement: Why Award and Contract Should be Government of India Union Audit Report 2000–1, Comptroller
Separated’, Discussion Paper No. 5/2000, Bonn Graduate and Auditor General of India, at www.cagindia.org
School of Economics, Bonn University, source: http:// Government of Orissa, (2001), White Paper on Orissa State Finances.
www.bgse.uni-bonn.de/papers/ Grewal, Bhajan S. (2000), ‘Australian Loan Council: Arrangements
Chelliah, Raja J. (1998), ‘Liberalisation, Economic Reforms and and Experience with Bailouts’, Research Network Working
Centre–State Relations’, in I.J. Ahluwalia and I.M.D. Little Paper No. R-397, Washington D.C.: Inter-American
(eds), India’s Economic Reforms and Development, Delhi: Oxford Development Bank.
University Press. Grout, P. (1984), ‘Investment and Wages in the Absence of Binding
Corts, K.S. (2002), ‘Fixed-Price vs. Cost-Plus: The Determinants Contracts: A Nash Bargaining Approach’, Econometrica Vol.
of Contractual Forms in Offshore Drilling’, Unpublished 52 No. 2, pp. 449–60.
Paper, Harvard University, source: http://www.people.hbs/edu/ Hayek, Friedrich A. von (1945), ‘The Use of Knowledge in Society’,
kcorts/turnkey.pdf American Economic Review, pp. 519–30.
Fiscal and Procurement Processes 117

Jin, Hehui, Yingyi Qian, and Barry Weingast (1999), ‘Regional Rao, M. Govinda (2000), ‘Linking Central Grants to Revenue
Decentralisation and Fiscal Incentives: Federalism, Chinese Deficit Reduction by States’, Economic and Political Weekly,
Style’, Working Paper, Department of Economics, Stanford Vol. XXXV No. 23, 3 June, pp. 1883–4.
University. Rao, M. Govinda and Sen (1996), Fiscal Federalism in India:
Laffont, J.J. and J. Tirole (1993), A Theory of Incentives in Theory and Practice, Delhi: Macmillan India.
Procurement and Regulation, MIT Press. Reserve Bank of India (2002), State Finances: A Study of Budgets
Lahiri, A. and S. Fardoust, (2000), Indian States: The Road to of 2002–3, Mumbai.
Reform, Paper presented at the India States Reform Forum, Rodden, Jonathan and Gunnar Eskeland (forthcoming), ‘Lessons
and Conclusions’, in Jonathan Rodden, Gunnar Eskeland,
New Delhi. www.statesforum.org
and Jenny Litvack (eds), Fiscal Decentralization and the
Mahendra Dev, S. and J. Mooij, Social Sector Expenditures and
Challenge of Hard Budget Constraint, Washington D.C.: World
Budgets: An Analysis of Patterns and the Budget Making Process Bank and Cambridge, Mass: M.I.T. Press.
in India in the 1990s, Centre for Economic and Social Studies, Rose-Ackerman, S. (1999), Corruption and Government: Causes,
Hyderabad. Consequences and Reform, Cambridge: Cambridge University
Milgrom, P. (1989), ‘Auction and Bidding: A Primer’, Journal of Press.
Economic Perspectives Vol. 3 No. 3, pp. 3–22. Sarma, E.A.S. (2001), Quality of Government Expenditure: A Review,
Morris, Sebastian, Rakesh Basant, Keshab Das, Kavil Ramachandran Paper presented at the conference on India: Fiscal Policies to
and Abraham Koshy (2001), Growth and Transformation of Accelerate Economic Growth, New Delhi.
Small Firms in India, New Delhi: Oxford University Press. Schiavo-Campo, S. and D. Tommasi (1999), Managing Government
Norton, A. and D. Elson (2002), What’s Behind The Budget? Expenditure, Asian Development Bank.
Politics, Rights and Accountability in the Budget Process, Overseas Seitz, Helmut (2000), ‘Sub-national Government Bailouts in
Development Institute, 2002. Germany’, Research Network Working Paper No. R-396, p.
Oates, Wallace E. (1972), Fiscal Federalism, New York: Harcourt, 18, Washington D.C.: Inter-American Development Bank.
Brace and Jovanovich. Shah, Anwar (1998), ‘Fiscal Federalism and Macroeconomic
Premchand, A. and S. Chattopadhyay (2001), Fiscal Adjustment Governance: For Better or For Worse?’, Policy Research
and Expenditure Management, Paper presented at the conference Working Paper, Washington D.C.: World Bank.
on India: Fiscal Policies to Accelerate Economic Growth, Srivastava, D.K. and Tapas K. Sen (2000), ‘Fiscal Federalism in
India: Issues Before the Eleventh Finance Commission’, in
New Delhi.
D.K. Srivastava (ed.), Fiscal Federalism in India: Contemporary
Qian, Yingyi and Gerard Roland (1998), ‘Federalism and the Soft
Challenges, New Delhi: National Institute of Public Finance
Budget Constraint’, American Economic Review, Vol. 88 No.
and Policy and Har-Anand Publications.
5, pp. 1143–62. Tiefer, C. and W. A. Shook (1999), Government Contract Law,
Raghuram, G. (2002), ‘Experiences of various forms of Commercial Carolina: Carolina Academic Press.
Partnership in Indian Railways’, India Infrastructure Report Williamson, O.E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism,
(2002), pp. 293–4, New Delhi, 3in Network and Oxford New York: Free Press.
University Press. Zhuravskaya, Ekaterina V. (2000), ‘Incentives to Provide Local
———(1978), Corruption: A Study in Political Economy, pp. 129– Public Goods: Fiscal Federalism, Russian Style’, Journal of
32 New York.: Academic Press. Public Economics, Vol. 76 No. 3, pp. 337–68.

You might also like