chapter 09

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 33

236 India Infrastructure Report 2003

9 RURAL INFRASTRUCTURE

9.1 IRRIGATION SUBSIDIES

A. Vaidyanathan

Huge and soaring subsidies, mostly in the form of SUBSIDIES AND THEIR ORIGIN
unrecovered costs of goods and services provided by the
public sector, are among the main causes underlying the Historically, under colonial rule, the government invested
fiscal crisis confronting the central and the state governments. in irrigation only if it could provide a reasonable rate of
In 1994–5, according to a recent National Institute of financial return after covering operating costs. This policy
Public Finance and Policy (NIPFP) study, the total subsidies had undergone a gradual change. Initially this criterion was
(implicit and explicit) of the central and the state governments relaxed for ‘protective’ works in areas liable to severe droughts
amounted to Rs 1,27,400 crore (Srivatsava and Sen, 1998). and recurrent famines. Subsequently social benefits of
By comparison, the public sector plan outlay in that year irrigation by way of increased agricultural production and
was Rs 98,200 crore and the gross fiscal deficit Rs 71,600 their indirect beneficial impact on the rural economy and
crore. The critical importance of reducing subsidies for government revenues came to be accepted as justifying
restoring the fiscal health of the public sector hardly needs investment in irrigation. Under planning, social cost–benefit
any emphasis. analysis came to be officially accepted as the basis for public
Subsidies under the head ‘irrigation’ amounted, in investment decisions in this sector. The requirement regarding
1994–5, to around Rs 14,000 crore or about one-eighths a minimum financial return was dropped. At the same time
of the total. Roughly half of this is on account of minor it was recognized that beneficiaries of public irrigation
irrigation works and flood control and drainage projects. projects should meet the costs incurred for providing water.
Major and medium projects, which are the focus of this Besides water charges based on area and crops irrigated in
section, account for somewhat over half of this figure. each season, most states had also passed legislation requiring
Up to the end of that year cumulative investments in this beneficiaries to pay a betterment levy to capture a part of
sector—mostly by state governments—amounted to around the increase in productivity and capital value of land due
Rs 45,000 crore. Operating costs (including operation to irrigation. The betterment levies did not yield much,
and maintenance (O&M), depreciation, and interest on mainly because the law was not enforced.
capital) amounted to Rs 7600 crore, of which, only
Rs 440 crore were recovered from users, leaving a loss Diluting Recovery
of Rs 7200–7300 crore to be borne by their general In the early 1970s, a National Irrigation Commission,
budgets. appointed by the Government of India (GOI, 1972), argued
that accepting social cost–benefit evaluation as the basis
This paper was discussed at a Conference on Fiscal Policies to
Accelerate Economic Growth organized by the National Institute of
for investment decisions does not minimize the ‘importance
Public Finance and Policy, May 2001. The author thanks the NIPFP of securing an adequate return from investment to irrigation
for their permission to publish it in this report. projects’ and recommended that ‘the financial return of a
Rural Infrastructure 237

project should also be examined at the time of approval and allowances. In fact there is widespread complaint that
and, if found inadequate to cover working expenses and increased salaries have cut into the amounts available for
indirect charges, water rates should be raised.’ In the carrying out maintenance and repair works. Inadequacy
event, the state governments did not comply with these of funds for this purpose is invariably cited as the reason
guidelines and losses incurred on account of public irrigation for deterioration of the systems and the quality of service
increased rapidly. they offer.
This trend was noted with concern by several official Capital costs rose because of three factors: general
committees and, in particular, successive Finance inflation; new projects being in more difficult locations;
Commissions. While emphasizing the necessity for improving and higher costs of borrowing. According to Central Water
cost recovery, they also progressively diluted the standards Commission (CWC) estimates (GOI, 1998), between
of cost recovery. Thus, the interest charges to be recovered 1976–7 and 1993–4, there was a four-fold increase in
from beneficiaries was lowered from 2.5 per cent of construction costs due to increases in prices of material
investment recommended by the Fifth Finance Commission and labour. Adjusting for inflation, the average investment
to 1 per cent by the subsequent two commissions. Faced per hectare of addition to irrigation potential rose two-and-
with failure to meet even this target, the Eighth Finance a-half to three times.3 Since interest on investments outlays
Commission chose to dilute it further and exhorted the during the construction of a project—and large irrigation
states to ensure that at least the maintenance costs be projects take several years to complete—are not included
recovered. But few states were willing to comply even with in project costs, these figures understate the cost of
this. irrigation projects to a significant extent.
Thus, in 1977–8, revenues from water charges under1 The average cost of government borrowing, which was
major, medium and multi-purpose works were around Rs less than 4 per cent in the early 1970s, has also risen
100 crore which fell short of working expenses (costs of sharply following change in the government’s interest-rate
O and M) by nearly Rs 30 crore. Inclusive of interest on policy in 1974. It averaged 5.6 per cent in 1977–8 and
accumulated investments in that category of works up to was a shade more than 12 per cent in 1993–4.
that year (at the average interest rate on the outstanding Revenues have not kept pace with costs: collections
debt of state governments as a whole) and depreciation (at which were just under Rs 100 crore in 1977–8 rose to
1 per cent of the cumulated investment, the loss amounted Rs 140 crore in 1987–8 and an estimated Rs 490 crore
to Rs 420 crore). By 1994–5 the latest year for which data in 1994–5. In 1977–8 revenues covered three- fourths of
on revenue and operating expenses are available—total the ‘working expenses’ but only a sixth of the total cost
recurring costs (inclusive of depreciation and interest) had (including interest and depreciation). By 1987–8, revenue
increased fourteen-fold but revenue realizations increased covered barely a quarter of working expenses, and 6 per
somewhat less than four-and-a-half times. Overall losses in cent of total cost. The position has vastly worsened since:
1994–5 were around Rs 7,000 crore compared to Rs 430 the recovery rates in 1993–4 fell to less than 15 per cent
crore in 1977–8. Since then the situation has certainly has of working expenses and 5 per cent of the total cost.
deteriorated further2.
‘Populism’
Cost Inflation The main reason of course is that water rates have become
Both working expenses and capital charges have increased a political hot potato and (along with electricity) a major
at a rapid pace. Working expenses have increased from focus of competitive populism. Raising water rates is seen
around Rs 130 crore in 1977–8 to an estimated Rs 1700 as an invitation to electoral disaster and few governments,
crore in 1994–5 partly due to expansion in the number irrespective of party affiliation, are willing to take the risk.
of staff but mostly on account of the steep rise in salaries The Committee on Pricing of Irrigation Water (GOI,
1972) noted:
1
Revision of water rates has been infrequent, hesitant
It is not clear whether cesses on irrigated crops are fully covered
by this estimate. In some cases (for example, Tamil Nadu) areas
and very much less than the increase in costs. For instance,
irrigated by old projects do not pay a separate water fee. Instead it water rates in Tamil Nadu were last revised thirty years
is integrated into the land revenue assessment which is not included back. In Punjab, Kerala, Haryana, Jammu and Kashmir,
in the above figures. Revenue from sale of water from irrigation
projects for non-agricultural uses is also not covered. The degree of 3 At a rough estimate cumulated capital investment in major and
underestimation on these accounts is, however, unlikely to be large medium irrigation at current prices increased 7 ½ times between
at the national level but could be significant in some states. 1977–8 and 1994–5 and by about 3 ½ to 4 times in constant prices.
2 NIPFP is currently in the process of updating the estimation During that period irrigation potential of these projects increased
up to 1988–9. from 24.7 mha to 31.8 mha, that is, by about 30 per cent.
238 India Infrastructure Report 2003

Table 9.1.1
Estimated Losses on Account of Major and Medium Irrigation and Multi-purpose River Valley Projects, India

(Rs crore)
1977–8 1987–8 1994–5
1 Gross Revenuea 97 139 440
2 Working expenses a 127 493 1700
3 Depreciation b 60 223 450
4 Interest on Capital c 336 1787 5330
5 Total cost (2+3+4) 523 2500 7480
6 Deficit (5-1) 426 2361 7040
7 Cumulative investments in major and medium 6000 22300 44900
multipurpose river valley projects d
8 Total outstanding debt of states e 4700 60720 160000
9 Total interest payments f 822 4879 19410
10 Average interest rate period (9)/(8)*100 560 800 12010
Notes: aCWC estimates. Figures for 1977–8 and 1987–8 as cited in GOI, 1992 for 1994–5 as cited in Srivatsava and Sen, 1997
p. 7. Planning Commission estimates for working expenses in 1994–5 is Rs 2970 crore which seems primafacie high. We have used
a lower figure based on the assumption that working expenses of major and medium works grew at the same rate as total revenue
expenditure on all Irrigation and flood control projects.
b1 per cent of cumulative investments up to end of each year.
cComputed by applying an interest rate (row 10) to corresponding figures in row 7.
dCWC 1998, p. 267, investment in 1994–5 estimated at Rs 4500 crore.
e&f various issues of RBI’s annual reports on Currency and Finance.
The estimated losses in this table differ from those given in other sources notably GOI, 1992, Mundle and Rao, 1991 and Srivatsava
and Sen, 1998. The estimates of the Committee on Irrigation Pricing (GOI, 1992) for capital charges are based on cumulated
investments up to three years before the year indicated in each column while the figures in this table are based on cumulated
investments up to and including each year. There are also some differences in the estimated average interest rates. Estimates of
Srivatsava and Sen cover not only major, medium and river valley projects but also minor irrigation, flood control, drainage and
command area development. Estimates of capital charges by CWC (1998) and that of Planning Commission for 1994–5 (cited
in Srivatsava and Sen, 1998) do not include depreciation and use lower interests rates.

and Himachal Pradesh, there has been no change since years. But at least one state, Punjab, has decided to give
the mid-1970s. Several (including Andhra Pradesh, Bihar, water free. There is no authenticated data on their
Gujarat, Karnataka, Madhya Pradesh, Orissa, Rajasthan, implementation or impact on revenues. Whether even
Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal) announced revisions during these revisions in states like Maharashtra and Andhra
1981–6. But the implementation was held up in some (eg. Pradesh will be large enough to meet soaring costs (narrowly
Gujarat, Karnataka) by the government. In the case of defined to cover working expenses with adequate provisions
Andhra Pradesh stay orders from courts prevented for routine maintenance and repair works but excluding
implementation. The rate increases were themselves rather capital charges) is in doubt.
modest and no state has accepted, much less implemented, Not only were rates not raised, but experience has also
the Irrigation Commission recommendations by reviewing shown that enforcement of the prescribed rates is far from
and adjusting rates every five years. Only Maharashtra has, strict. There is ample scope in the existing arrangement for
within the past year broken from this pattern both in terms collusion between officials and farmers leading to
of magnitude of increase in rates and announcing a understatement of area irrigated, especially of area under
graduated increase every year for the next five years. crops carrying higher rates. Laxity in assessment is
More recent information compiled by the Planning compounded by laxity in collection. The committee on
Commission4 shows that the situation has not changed Pricing of Irrigation Water found that actual revenue
materially. Uttar Pradesh and Bihar announced revisions collection fell short of demand (that is, assessments) in a
in 1995 and Andhra Pradesh in 1997. Maharashtra has majority of states. During the late 1980s there was little or
maintained its policy of graduated increase over several no shortfalls in Haryana and Punjab. They were marginal
in Uttar Pradesh and substantial (ranging from 27 to 70 per
4 Thanks are due to B.N. Navalwala, Adviser, Planning cent) in the others. Accumulated arrears—which do not
Commission, for making this information available. include remissions and waivers granted by governments
Rural Infrastructure 239

from time to time—were found to be nearly as large as to provide them with water. This means that investments
the annual demand in some cases, and three to four times in ongoing works, which are yet to begin delivering water,
in several states. Little wonder that losses on account of must be excluded while fixing rates. More important, users
irrigation have recorded a phenomenal increase.5 must not be required to bear the costs of over- capitalization
due to over design, poor design and inefficiencies/leakages
in construction. There are innumerable instances where
IMPROVING COST RECOVERY the actual area irrigated turns out to be much less than
The situation is clearly untenable and unconscionable. expected because of over-estimation of water availability,
failure to enforce crop patterns on the basis of which the
Untenable because of the huge and mounting fiscal deficits
project was designed, and because transmission and
of the state, which have severely constrained their capacity
distribution losses are higher than assumed.
even to maintain, let alone increase, investments in
It is difficult to assess, even approximately, the magnitude
expansion and improvement of social and economic
of the adjustments to allow for these factors. In the absence
infrastructure. Unconscionable because a good part of the
of an independent and objective assessment of what a
unrecovered costs is in the nature of continuing subsidies
reasonably well-designed and efficiently executed project
to farmers whose income increase substantially as a result
would cost, adjustments will necessarily be arbitrary. The
of irrigation. Moreover, a large proportion of benefits go
suggestion by the Committee on Irrigation Pricing whereby
to relatively better-off farmers. The resulting squeeze on
the basis at tim (t) is taken as the cumulated investments
public resources means less investments in extending and
up to year (t – 3) is one way. Another will be to leave out
improving irrigation, education and health facilities, and investments which have not yet resulted in additional
other schemes for the benefit of other, less fortunate, irrigation. Either way the base for estimating capital charges
groups. Measures to reduce the un-recovered costs of to be recovered for users will be substantially smaller than
public irrigation are therefore imperative. Raising water the total cumulated investments to date.
rates has to be an essential and important component of As for working expenses, establishment costs are high
these measures but not the only one. A number of other because of over-staffing, and relatively high salaries. The
related issues need to be clarified before deciding the sharp increase in salary level in the last two decades has been
extent and pattern of increases in water charges. a major reason for the rapid increase in working expenses.
On the other hand there are complaints that the number
Beyond O&M Recovery of staff for maintenance and water regulation at the ground
The notion that it is enough to recover (O&M) costs is level as well as outlays on maintenance/repair works is
ill founded. Amortization and interest on capital invested grossly inadequate and that the works done are costly and
in the projects are as much part of the cost of providing of poor quality. What the optimum level of expenditure on
irrigation as the working expenses. Governments can afford regular maintenance should be depends to a significant
to consider bearing part or all of it if they have substantial extent on the manner in which the activity is organized and
revenue surpluses in their budgets. Even then, whether managed. The present system depends entirely on the state
beneficiaries of public irrigation systems are more deserving beauracracy which, besides being expensive, has little
of subsidies than others is questionable. The case for such incentive to manage costs. With appropriate autonomy and
subsidies is totally untenable when indiscriminate financial responsibility, a significant difference in maintenance
subsidization of public services, financed almost entirely and performance can be expected especially if users have
out of borrowings at high interest rates, are the major reason a stake and actively participate in management.
for governments budgets being in the red. So long as the While users at present have little financial stake in the
systems which supply them water—and this situation is
revenue budget is in deficit and public investments cannot
unlikely to change significantly—experience (notably in
be maintained at levels needed to sustain a reasonable rate
Andhra Pradesh) has shown that entrusting responsibility
of overall growth, the principle of full cost recovery must
for state-funded maintenace works to water-user associations
apply to irrigation and indeed to many other goods and
makes a significant improvement in terms of relevance and
services provided by the public sector.
appropriateness of works as well as their quality and cost.
Making users associations bear the responsibility for both
Exclusion of Waste from Cost Assessment
funding and execution of maintenance and repair below
But fairness also requires that users be charged on the basis the outlet level could be one way of improving cost recovery6.
of investments required, at reasonable levels of efficiency, 6 For a case study of water users managing the distributories of
the irrigation system in Orissa see Chapter 9.2 by Binayak Rath in
5 For details see chapter 6 in GOI, 1992. this report.
240 India Infrastructure Report 2003

This is neither novel nor radical: local irrigation systems should not be disproportionately large in relation to the
in India have a long tradition of user management and increase in productivity due to irrigation and that steep
users meeting the cost of maintenance, repair and increases will not be justified unless the quality of irrigation
beneficiary contributions in the form of labour, cash and service improves significantly. In this connection, it is worth
material besides involvement in the organizations. noting that on the average, during the early 1980s, a hectare
Even after adjusting for all the above factors, current of irrigated land produced Rs 2400 more than a hectare of
levels of revenue realized are likely to fall well short of rain-fed crops.7 Assuming that on the whole, average
required level. Full cost recovery in 1994–5 (with capital productivity per hectare has been rising at the same rate on
charges based on cumulated investments up to the end of both categories of land, the difference, at 1986–7 prices, in
1991–2) calls for a ten-fold rise in actual collections over the early 1990s would be around Rs 3200 per hectare.
current levels. Adjusting for price changes—WPI for agricultural
It is clearly difficult to get politicians to even consider, commodities roughly doubled between 1986–7 and 1994–
leave alone implement, a steep revision in one go. A graduated 5—the differential in 1993–4 would be around Rs 6400
approach is thus essential. The first step would be to per hectare. The realization of irrigation charges from major
rationalize the existing area-based rates on the basis of the and medium works in that year averaged around Rs 200
relative irrigation requirements by season and crop in per hectare which amounts to about 3 per cent of the
different regions. It would approximate to a volumetric incremental productivity of irrigated land.
charge without actually having to measure volumes delivered Full cost recovery, which calls for a ten-fold rise in revenue,
to individual users. This could be followed by the strategy would mean that farmers will have to pay nearly 30 per cent
adopted by Maharashtra whereby a progressive increase in of the incremental productivity of irrigated land as water
rates over a five-year period is announced in advance. This charge. This would naturally be considered unreasonably
way users can be given clear advance signals of the high. However, one must also bear in mind the following
government, long-term aims regarding the level of cost factors which reduce effective incidence even at current low
recovery, as well as reasonable time for them to adjust their rates: (1) The above estimates of the differential between
use patterns accordingly. irrigated and rain-fed productivity is understated; (2) there
is considerable under recording of total area irrigated by
Indexation of Tariffs major and medium works, especially of area under crops
carrying higher rates; and (3) the assessed dues are not fully
The aim should be to give a clear indication that full cost
collected. They underscore the importance of scrupulously
recovery is to be achieved over a period. For this purpose,
strict assessments of crop-wise areas irrigated and of ensuring
governments should adopt a policy of automatic indexation
that dues are collected fully and promptly. In both respects
of water rates to O&M costs or product prices. If such
the quality of governance of irrigation systems leaves much
a policy had been followed from the 1970s, the increase
to be desired.
required to meet capital charges would have been more
manageable. Thus, the Wholesale Price Index (WPI) in
Convergence to Full Cost Recovery
1993–4 was nearly four times the level in 1977–8. Assuming
no change in collection efficiency, indexing water rates to The extent of rate increases will obviously depend on the
the Wholesale Price Index would have raised revenues to incidence of under-assessment and leakages. The extent of
Rs 2100 crore by 1993–4, compared to the actual realization the latter is not known; they are also likely to vary a great
of Rs 450 crore. The required realization for full cost deal between regions. It is, therefore, essential to commission
recovery would have been only 2½ times the collection on a systematic and objective assessment for each system of the
the basis of indexed rate which is far less formidable area actually receiving irrigation, the area under various
compared to the ten-fold rise needed on the basis of current crops and their productivity. Even after these adjustments,
realizations. Graduated additions over the indexed rate there is no doubt that full cost recovery will mean a substantial
could then be made in such a way that capital charges can increase in the incidence of water charges relative to output
also be recovered fully over a specified period of ten years. at current levels of water use efficiency and productivity.
The credibility of the government’s intention about its Phased raising of rates must, therefore, go along with
goal and its seriousness about fairness to users will be measures to make fuller, more effective use of available
enhanced if a mechanism is created for an independent
review of reported investments in all projects to allow for 7 This is based on a simple average of estimated productivity of
over-design and inefficiencies in determining the base for irrigated and rain-fed cropped areas. They relate to the period 1979–
determining capital charges. Such an approach has, however, 83 and valuations are at 1986–7 prices. For details, see Vaidyanathan
to contend with the argument that an increase in rates et al., 1994.
Rural Infrastructure 241

water and for managing its allocation and scheduling to Committee on Irrigation Pricing
achieve higher output per unit of water use. That there
It is on the basis of the above reasoning that the Committee
is much scope for both is widely recognized but seldom
on Irrigation Pricing stressed the necessity to view the strategy
quantified. Data on actual water deliveries and area irrigated
for reform of water pricing as part of a larger programme
for a number of projects (Table 9.1.2) suggest that the
of modernization of irrigation systems and the restructuring
amount of irrigation water used is in most cases far in excess
of their management. Large investments will of course be
of the deficit of rainfall relative to crop water requirement.
needed for physical improvements; and they should command
Rules and criteria for allocation/scheduling are fuzzy and
higher priority than construction of new systems. The planning
enforcement notoriously lax. Systems are not equipped with
of these works also needs considerable improvement based
engineering structures to permit effective regulation of water
on the experience of the National Watenr Management
distribution according to such rules as there are; water
Projects (NWMP) projects and using better data and more
delivery is amenable to change through influence and
sophisticated analytical tools. But far more challenging is the
pressure; and few systems can ensure that timing and
task of restructuring the management.
quantum of water supply is so managed as to achieve the
Experience has amply demonstrated that the present
maximum impact on productivity.
system, whereby the government assumes the responsibility
There is large scope and need for a major overhaul of
from conception through design, evaluation, financing and
the distribution network, repairing and installing devices
construction of irrigation systems as well as their continuing
for regulating water deliveries to different segments and
management, wholly through its bureaucracy, is incapable
redesign of the networks in the light of actual experience
of achieving the above objectives. The entire process at
in respect of water yield, losses in conveyance and
every stage is far too opaque, open to interference and mani-
application, crop patterns, and conjunctive use of water.
pulation, without any effective incentive or mechanism to
This needs to be accompanied by reformulation in clearer
ensure economical use of resources in construction and
and more precise terms of rules regarding crop pattern and
management or to ensure that costs are fully recovered.
delivery schedules as well as a restructuring of the
Besides introducing transparent criteria and procedures to
organization to achieve greater transparency and tighter
judge the soundness and viability of projects before they go
management. These measures, which together should make
on stream, the management of systems must be insulated
a substantial difference to the productivity of water, need
from external interferences from politicians, the bureaucracy,
to be accompanied by measures to ensure stricter assessment
and the local power centres.
and collection of dues. All this will reduce the effective
incidence of full cost recovery rates in relation to output
Users Involvement
and income of the beneficiaries of irrigation and help
make the case for rate enhancement stronger and more Beneficiaries of projects (new ones as well as modernized
persuasive. old ones) must be required to contribute a share of the

Table 9.1.2
Frequency Distribution of Irrigation Depth in Selected Projects/States

State Season PET minus


80% of No. of Projects by Depth of Irrigation in Metres 2
rainfall1
Nil or NA 0–0.2 0.2–0.4 0.4–0.6 0.6–0.8 1.0-1.5 <1.5
Andhra Kharif .135 – – 1 – 1 1 6
Pradesh Rabi .497 – – – – 4 2 3
Karnataka Kharif .164 2 – 1 2 5 6 3
Rabi .496 8 – 1 2 5 4 2
Madhya Kharif .138 9 2 2 – 3 – 2
Pradesh Rabi .369 2 1 2 3 8 3 2
Tamil Nadu Kharif .342 7 – – 1 3 4 1
Rabi .357 – – – 1 6 6 3
Notes: 1Maximum estimated values among different agro-climatic zones of each state computed from annexure 7 of GOI, 1992
2Computed from Annex 4.1 of GOI, 1992
3Kharif 15 June–15 October
4Rabi 15 October–15 March
242 India Infrastructure Report 2003

costs (which is necessary to give them a sense of stake and on well-defined contracts between them and the system
ownership).8 This can take the form of direct contributions management defining their respective entitlements and
in the form of labour, cash or materials for the project obligations, is also aimed to create strong internal incentives
as a whole; entrusting the responsibility for constructing for efficient and accountable management.
field channels and preparing lands below the outlet level
for irrigation; or compensating the displaced people by PROSPECTS FOR REFORM
giving a part of their land. The sense of stake will be
enhanced by ensuring that potential beneficiaries as well To outline a plausible, coherent package of reforms is one
as those adversely affected are consulted in deciding the thing and getting it implemented is quite another. Political
basic operational rules (governing the damarcation of areas parties are still, for the most part, unwilling to confront the
to be benefited, compensating project-affected people, issue of cost recovery in water (or, for that matter, in most
allocation between different uses, permissible crop patterns other sectors), much less to seriously discuss raising user
and scheduling of water under different contingencies). charges. They continue to see any attempt to do so as
The continuing management should be entrusted to suicidal. At the same time there are signs that the perilous
autonomous organizations with powers to make, change condition of state finances and the inability to find resources
and enforce rules, levy and collect water rates on condition for socio-economic infrastructure to support growth and
that they become financially self-reliant. poverty alleviation is forcing at least a few of them to address
the issue. There are also signs—as yet limited and diffused—
Table 9.1.3 of farmers taking active interest in improving the quality
Illustrative Calculations of Increase in Collections for
of irrigation. The creation of water-user associations and the
Full Cost Recovery in 1994–5
declared commitment of the governments to ‘turn over’
Rs crore management to users seems to have kindled both awareness
Costs
and interest in these matters among the farming community.
Working expenses 1700 Properly mobilized through persistent and patient efforts on
Depreciation1 340 the part of the media and the political leaders to explain
Interest 4080 the necessity and rationale for reform—could build a strong
ALL 6120 grassroots, pressure for reform.
Revenues
Actual realization 440 Turning Point?
Potential revenues with index rate at 1850
Fairly wide-ranging organizational reforms are already on
current level of enforcement2
Potential revenues with index rate and 2310
the agenda of several states: Andhra Pradesh, Orissa and
strict enforcement 3 Tamil Nadu have enacted legislation envisaging major changes
in the organization for water development. Some—notably
Notes: 1Based on cumulated investment up to end 1991–2 Andhra Pradesh and Maharashtra—have taken significant
(Rs 33,700 crore). and, given the current political situation, bold steps to raise
2Wholesale price index in 1994–5 was 4.2 times the 1977–8 level
3Assuming 20% leakage due to under-assessment and laxity in water rates. Andhra Pradesh has perhaps gone the farthest
collection, this was the average shortfall as per cent of demand in
in implementing reforms: It has legislated water-user
10 states during 1986–90 (GOI, 1992: chapter 5).
participation at all levels of each major and medium irrigation
system; and legislation has been followed by elections. It also
The internal structures of these organizations must be shows that given strong backing from political leaders in
such that user representatives participate in all levels and government, the attitude of the bureaucracy can be changed
functions of management. While contribution to capital from one of cynical indifference to a positive and active
costs gives them a sense of ownership, involvement in interest in reforms and serious engagement in addressing
management provides them space and opportunities to evolve the problems they throw up. As already noted, entrusting
generally acceptable allocation rules/criteria, monitor the maintenance and repair to the local WUAs rather than
actual performance of the system and resolve conflicts through contractors has given a strong sense of involvement on the
a process of internal negotiation and compromise. It also part of users resulting in speedier completion of works at
provides a better mechanism for adapting rules in the light lower cost and better quality than under the earlier
of changing conditions. The intention behind the suggestion dispensation. However, as yet, much remains to be done.
to have user associations at different tiers and the insistence The precise functions of the management committees at
the higher levels of each system, the relative roles of the
8 The subsequent suggestions are essentially a summary of the government officials and user representatives in decision-
detailed recommendations of the Committee on Irrigation Pricing. making, the powers of the system-level boards in deciding
Rural Infrastructure 243

operational rules, procedures, rates, etc. and the relation government to the principle of full cost recovery and a clear
between the system-level organization and the government time-frame for achieving the objective. The really difficult
remain ill-defined. There is still reluctance to committing the task of restructuring irrigation management still lies ahead.

9.2 PEOPLE’S PARTICIPATION FOR EFFICIENT AND ACCOUNTABLE


MANAGEMENT OF IRRIGATION SYSTEMS

Binayak Rath

While the Irrigation Department regulates the demand and India to bring in a people-centric approach (World Bank,
supply of water, the cropping patterns are suggested by the 1993). Since water is a state subject in our federal structure,
Agriculture Department and the collection of water rates many state governments have announced their water policies
and cess is vested with the revenue administration! This in tune with the National Policy with a focus on
fragmentation leads to none of the departments being fully participation of farmers through institutional arrangements
responsible for revenue collection. such as Water Users Association (WUA) Pani Panchayats
Management of public irrigation systems has been (PPs). We examine the scope of the PP scheme introduced
problematic, and only a fraction of the gains possible in in 1996 and its impact on efficiency and accountability
agriculture are realized. Improper pricing of water has been through a case study of the developments in Orissa.
recognized as one of the key problems in this
mismanagement. Recoveries today do not even cover PANI PANCHAYATS
operations and maintenance (O&M) costs. Other aspects
of dysfunctionalities in the system are not widely recognized. Despite Orissa’s endowment of vast water resources in its
Recognition of the potential of the participation of farmers river systems, almost every year it faces the problem of
and civil society in conceptualization and design as well as drought or floods. Proper management of its irrigation and
O&M of the irrigation networks, which could have made flood control systems could have mitigated these problems.
possible easy solutions in management, is only the beginning. Many of the older irrigation systems operate far below
In spite of significant physical achievement of acreage covered capacity due to poor management. Shortage of funds and
under irrigation, the country faces the paradox of drought- poor maintenance have similarly made many irrigation
flood-drought, syndrome that severely affects agricultural schemes defunct. The present practice of budgetary allocation
production and yields. It is estimated that while one-third based on ayacut-certification by the revenue authorities, low
of our land is subjected to drought one-eighth of cultivable water rates, collections in which the department has no role
land is subjected to flood. to play, poor incentives for people to use water optimally,
One can say that the state management of irrigation are the main causes of poor performance of the irrigation
projects has failed miserably in our country. It was even projects. Poor functioning of CADA could not generate
noted by the Public Accounts Committee on Irrigation enthusiasm among farmers to participate in irrigration
(1983): ‘The entire planning process of irrigation project management. There was little space for the users, with a
is faulty. There have been serious slippages in major and natural interest in augmenting water resources, to be brought
medium irrigation projects.’ There are instances when the in. Irrigation systems, including the lower canals and
authorities find it difficult to operate and maintain projects distributories have aspects of common property resources.
with the amount of grant received from the Government So, there is prima facie meaning in involving users in
budget (Rath, 1993; Mitra, 1998). There is no incentive for management, through appropriate frameworks and
efficiency or accountability in the system. In addition to institutions. Given the poor condition of much of the
many planning and design-level problems, administrative irrigation systems, such involvement of users has vast
problems arise during execution and O&M of the projects. potential to improve incomes and reduce poverty. The
In view of these problems, the National Water Policy, 1987, Government of Orissa realized the need to take further the
had laid great emphasis on farmers’ participation in irrigation agenda laid out by the National Water Policy.
management. In the post-liberalization period, the World Accordingly, it enacted a new State Water Policy that
Bank, which had supported our irrigation development and introduced some amendments in the Orissa Irrigation Act
funded our Command Area Development Approach (1959), Orissa Irrigation Rules (1961) as well as its Revised
(CADA) programmes, have urged the Government of Rules (1974). The new policy inter alia envisaged a
244 India Infrastructure Report 2003

reorganization in the structure of administration. The it was decided to hand over a part of the network of the canal
Department of Water Resources (DOWR) was reorganized system for its O&M to appropriately formed PPs WUAs.
and a Water Resource Board was created in 1993 to plan, In the first phase, the government identified four pilot projects,
execute and coordinate the utilization of the water resources viz., Ghodahada and Rushikulya Distributary No.11 of Ganjam
of the state. The Government of Orissa also approached, District, Aunli and Derjang Projects of Angul District, and
in 1994, international funding agencies like the World the initiatives for forming PPs started in 1996. Consultancy
Bank and the Department For International Development assignments were given to different non-government
(DFID) for funds to renovate the projects. Through their organizations (NGOs) to undertake the preliminary spade-
post- evaluation studies these organizations identified the work as well as to communicate and motivate the farmers
weaknesses in the system and then advised the government to participate in PPs. The selected NGOs and the Water and
on how to bring about people’s participation in irrigation Land Management Institute (WALMI) of the Government
management. They also advised gradual disinvestment in of Orissa demonstrated the benefits of PPs. Minor maintenance
the irrigation sector. The new policy of the state creates activities by farmers eased flow of water up to the tail reaches.
and gives responsibility to the institution of the PP for all They were also helped to organize water distribution, resolve
aspects of water planning and management. The idea is disputes, if any, and adopt their own crop planning, etc in
to hand over the O&M of irrigation systems to the users consultation with agronomists. With the help of the NGOs,
in due course. PPs were introduced on a pilot basis in 1996 50 PPs were registered as legal bodies in the four command
and the scheme’s success led the government to legalize areas. Under the new arrangement responsibility for O&M
people’s involvement in management through Orissa of the reservoir/diversion weir (as the case may be) of dam,
Irrigation (Amendment) Rules, 1999. spillways, sluices, primary, and secondary distribution
For better and sustainable O&M it recognizes the need networks, etc. rests with the DOWR. But the responsibility
to involve farmers especially at the lowest level of the for O&M of the tertiary system, that is, below minor/sub-
distribution system. As a first step to this process of change, minor, is vested with the PPs.

Box 9.2.1
The 1987 N ational Water P
National olicy
Policy

In 1987, the Government of India announced its ‘National Water Policy’, that recognized water as a prime natural resource and
a basic need. It was further envisaged that the planning and development of water and related land resources should be directed
to improve the quality of life as well as the environment. The policy laid emphasis on:
• Integrated and multi-disciplinary approach to the planning, formulation, clearance, and implementation of projects, including
catchment treatment and management, environmental and ecological aspects, the rehabilitation of affected people and command
area development. Focus on environmental impact assessment (EIA) during project planning;
• Promotion of appropriate organizational structure for management of water resources;
• Well-developed information systems;
• Maximizing availability of water to the users;
• Multi-purpose use of water resources as well as integrated and coordinated development of surface water and groundwater
and their conjunctive use;
• Proper maintenance and modernization of projects;
• Water allocation priorities in rank order: drinking, irrigation, hydro-power, navigation, industrial and other uses;
• Water allocation in terms of equity and social justice. Disparities in the availability of water between head-reach and tail-end
farms and between large and small farms to be alleviated by adoption of a rotational water distribution system and supply of water
on a volumetric basis;
• Participation of farmers and voluntary agencies in various aspects of management of irrigation systems (that is, participatory
irrigation management (PIM);
• Command Area Development Approach to ensure overall optimality;
• Fixation of water rates so as to convey the scarcity value of the resource to the users and to foster the motivation for economy
in water-use. The rates should be adequate to cover the annual O&M charges and a part of the fixed costs;
• Awareness about water conservation should be promoted through education, regulation, incentives and disincentives;
• Flood control and drought management as integral to water management;
• Training of both officials and users;
• Need to equip local government to cope with burdens imposed directly or indirectly by development projects;
• Need to move towards decentralized decision-making and eliminate interference that have restricted the authority of regional
and local officials in water management.
Rural Infrastructure 245

The formal handing over of the system to the people increase in rainfall during the kharif season of 2000–1
took place in April 2001 for 40 PPs out of the 50 registered (1.34 per cent) only the water supply at the outlets had
till date. All these PPs are enthusiastic in taking up their increased by 17 per cent.
respective canal systems. For handing over of the remaining • Higher productivity is noticed in the Derajang
systems to the PPs, work is on in full swing. Thereafter, command areas. Our field data show that per hectare
the government plans to extend the PP programme to other productivity of paddy in the kharif season had increased
areas. It has identified another 29 irrigation projects by 50 per cent in 1998–9 over that in 1997–8. Moreover,
covering an area of over 3 lakh hectares for its second the per hectare productivity of pulses had gone up by 62
phase where PP schemes are to be introduced. It is per cent, groundnut by 25 per cent, sesame by 5 per cent,
estimated that 688 PPs are to be formed to look after the and vegetables by 22 per cent. This increase has been
irrigation system in these projects. The success of the first maintained since then.
phase has given much confidence to go ahead and introduce • The cropping patterns too have changed. Earlier no
PIM among the farming community more generally. sunflower was grown in the command area owing to lack
WALMI takes an active part in the training of both officers of water, and no information or advice from the Agriculture
and farmers. Inaugurating the ‘Awareness Campaign’ of Department. Now sunflower cultivation has picked up and
‘PPs Programme’, the Chief Minister of Orissa, Naveen its yields have risen from 1350 kg per hectare in 1997–
Pattanaik, has recently reiterated that PPs will open the 8 to 1620 kg in 1998–9.
door to development by ensuring the direct participation • In Aunli too, data indicate a rising trend in the per
of farmers in the management of irrigation. Emphasizing hectare productivity of all the crops after introduction of
the need to transform the PPs into a ‘mass movement’ he PPs. The per hectare productivity of paddy has gone up
has indicated that very soon the ‘Biju Farmers Project’ will by 35 per cent, pulses by 56 per cent, groundnut by 33
be implemented in the state. The estimated budget of the per cent, seasame by 25 per cent, vegetables by 18 per
new project is Rs 1000 crore and 80 per cent of the funds cent and suga rcane has gone up by 20 per cent.
will be utilized through PPs. He has further assured that • Improved yields have raised benefits from land. The
tube-well irrigation would be enhanced and strengthened per hectare average annual benefits accruing to farmers
through the scheme of ‘Operation Trushna’, where, again, increased from Rs 2873 in 1995–6 to Rs 13,258 in 1999–
PPs would be introduced. Additionally, he has also proposed 2000, (that is, a four-fold increase!). This, of course,
disinvestment of the state-run ‘Tube-Well Corporation’. implies that the water rate paying capacity of the farmers
has gone up.
• The stipends paid to member beneficiaries who
IMPACT attended training programmes was retained by the WUAs/
PPs to purchase the much needed instruments for use in
Our post-evaluation study was undertaken in two project
measurement of water!
sites, namely, Derajang and Aunli Medium Irrigation
• The assurance of water has encouraged the farmers
Projects of Angul district. Field-work was carried out in
to use new high-yielding varieties of seeds.
June–July, 2001, and again in June 2002. In addition to
• The wastage of water from the canal/sub-canal head
the secondary data gathered from the Irrigation Department,
has reduced a great deal, by about 90 per cent.
at Angul, a specially designed questionnaire was canvassed
among the members of the PP in a few villages, that is, There are other intangible economic and social benefits
Gramashree Water Users Association and Swarnprasu Water that have followed the introduction of PPs.
User Association in the command area of Derjang project.
• Significant awareness among the farmers regarding
In addition we had extensive discussions with the field-
the benefits of PP has come about since their participation
level officials on different aspects of the PP. We fond that
in the training programmes and meetings organized by the
the institution of the PP scheme resulted in major economic
NGO and WALMI from time to time.
gains. Some of these are listed below:
• PPs have resulted in greater cooperation and
• Water available at the outlets has gone up. An coordination among the concerned officials and the member
examination of the water supply data at the outlets and the farmers. One of the beneficiaries reported that prior to
rainfall for 1995–6 to 1999–2000 for the Derajang project the formation of PPs, officials did not bother to hear them,
indicate that in spite of 82 per cent less rainfall during the when they went with any water-related problems. Then
rabi season of 1998–9, water supply in the corresponding their access to the officials of the Irrigation as well as the
period had increased by 47 per cent of the same period Agriculture Department was very limited. But now, since
in the earlier years. Similarly, though there was a small all those officials come to their ‘doorsteps,’ they get ample
246 India Infrastructure Report 2003

opportunity to interact with them and to bring out their • Farmers enjoy the freedom of choice with regard to
grievances and views on better distribution of water. These the crops they grow, since the amount of water they receive
and similar interactions have enhanced the awareness among is proportional to their land.
the farmers as well as among the officials. Farmers are • The officials of the Agriculture Department in their
optimistic and there is a distinct change in the attitude extension activities show much improved working.
of officials. These would, in the longer term, result in gains • The middle and higher level officials of the Irrigation
that are not evident at present. Department are enthused to push forward the idea of PPs
• Thus, already the accountability of the officials to because many of them feel that this will result in less
farmers (in terms of water availability) during the crop political interference in their day-to-day managerial
seasons as improved. functions, especially with regard to awarding contracts to
PPs are accountable to their members. Earlier, conflicts maintain the tertiary irrigation networks.
between neighbours regarding use of water, were common,
and the department officials did not bother to resolve
EMERGING CHALLENGES
them. Now farmers are able to resolve their disputes
themselves. It has generated a sense of ownership among The PPs have crossed only the first step of PIM, that is,
the farmers for the facilities created. A sense of unity and partial participation in O&M of the tertiary system. The
fellowship among the farmers has emerged. next two stages, namely, taking over of minors and sub-
• Farmers see the value of training and of workshops minors for direct O&M, and collections of water rates are
to improve their knowledge for their economic gains. yet to be implemented. We have identified a few contentious
• There is much less damage of the minors and the issues, which ought to be resolved to improve the
sub-minors. performances of the PPs and take the institution further.
• Political interference in the job contracts for the
minors and the sub-minors has also reduced considerably Insufficient Maintenance Fund: As per the agreement
as now the officials of the Irrigation Department ask the between the PPs and the Irrigation Department, in the
respective panchayats to provide the required number of second phase the PPs will be paid an amount of Rs 35
people for the job. per hectare per year as maintenance grant out of the
• To a large extent the distribution of water is equitable existing water rate of Rs 100 per hactare. But this rate
and there is no bias against the tail-end farmers. The ‘quota sharing is not acceptable to the PPs on the ground that
of water’ is proportionate to the Culturable Command the amount is insufficient to maintain the minors and sub-
Area (CCA) of the WUA. minors, since such work also involves the maintenance of
• Farmers have the right to bring through the Apex inspection roads alongside the minors and sub-minors.
Committee their suggestions for improvements in the The work also involves continual repair of the dykes
management of the main canal system, water delivery through the year, and also cleaning of the canal bed at least
schedule, etc. at the project level. twice a year to ensure smooth flow of water.

Box 9.2.2
Str uctur
ucturee of the ‘P
tructur ani P
‘Pani anchayat
anchayat’’
Panchayat

• The PPs are formed on a three-tier system with two informal associations and one formal association on minor/sub-minor
basis comprising an ayacut ranging between 300–600 hectares.
• Chak Committees per outlet are formed taking farmers, one each from the high land, middle land, and low land areas of the
ayacut. A representative from the Chak Committee will be a member of the executive body of the PP. Each PP will have a president,
secretary, and treasurer.
• Each beneficiary landowner within the ayacut of the concerned minor/sub-minor qualifies to be a member of the concerned
PP.
• For registering a PP, a minimum of 51 per cent of the beneficiaries, possessing 60 per cent of command area, are required
to be members. To be eligible as a member in a PP, a token membership fee of Rs 10, or as is decided by the PP, is charged.
• A fund is created in the form of share capital with the contributions made by the members of the PPs proportionate to their
land holding plus a part of the water rates (Rs 35 per acre) in order to take up maintenance work of canals or to attend any work
of emergent nature. The authorized office bearers of the PP have powers to spend out of these funds.
• An ‘Apex Committee’ in each command area, comprising of all the presidents of the WUAs and with invited official members
would prepare the canal operation schedules, O&M plans of the system, suggest cropping patterns and undertake the overall
co-ordination among the PPs.
Rural Infrastructure 247

Difficulty in Collecting Water Fees: As per the policy and water to them and they insist that the main canal should
agreement, in the third phase the PPs will be responsible be cleaned every month during its operation period.
for the collection of ‘water fees’ from their members along
No Effort to Collect Reveneue: The present practice of
with the distribution of water and maintenance of the
collection of water rates from the farmers is replete with
minors and the sub-minors. But, in this respect, the
many loopholes which need to be urgently reviewed. The
members have expressed their concerns, with regard to the
present practice wherein the revenue officials certify the
task of collection of ‘water fees’ from all the members. They
irrigation ayacut after a joint verification by the staff of both
feel that it will be an uphill task for them and this will lead
Revenue and Irrigation Departments provides no challenge
to conflicts among the office bearers and the irrigators.
for the officials of Irrigation Department. They do not even
Their argument is that when the District Magistrate (DM) know how much area is certified by the Revenue Department
and his army of officials, who are armed with all the official and how many farmers are charged, and at what rates. The
powers including a police force, have failed to collect the lack of involvement of the irrigation officials in water rate
water rates properly under the present system, how can and cess collection is one of the major reasons for the poor
they discharge the same function smoothly under similar health of many irrigation projects in the state.
circumstances? Many raise questions like: Are PPs more As the DM/Collector is assigned all revenue collection
powerful than the DM? on behalf of the government, he does not bother to know
Lack of Commitment of the Government: According to the or keep track of the revenue coming from particular heads
of account. As soon as his earmarked quota (which is
PPs the government has not made any serious effort to fulfil
assigned to each DM) is fulfilled, his effort in collecting
its promises made at the time of the agreement. According
the rest of the dues wanes. Thus, the present practice of
to the president of the Apex Committee, though machinery
revenue collection is hardly geared towards efficient
worth Rs 6 lakh had been promised at the initial stage for
collection. There are no incentives for improved collections.
common use by the farmers, they have not received the same.
The rise in crop productivity and the subsequent increase
Constraint of Field Channel: We noted that there are no in net income of the farmers indicate that the water rate
field channels in the ayacut area. In their absence some paying capacity of the farmers has gone up. The government
farmers have made temporary earthen channels, which should exploit this opportunity to collect the arrears in
break often. The flooding method that this results in leads water charges from the farmers as their ability to pay has
to wastage of water and reduces the amount that is available gone up substantially.The water rate collection could be
to tail-end farmers. assigned to the irrigation authorities on an incentive system
(both individual and collective) where part of any additional
Technical Problems: The topography and climate of the collection over the targeted one could be shared by the field
command area results in quick growth of weeds inside the officials who are responsible for collection.
main canals that results in the reduced velocity of water and PIM with the improvements as suggested, especially with
raises the Full Storage Level (FSL) which further obstructs regard to collection of water rates, is crucial to the efficient
the free flow of water to the minors and sub-minors. Hence, and accountable working of irrigation systems. PIM ought
the PPs are apprehensive of the availability of sufficient to be extended to irrigation projects over much of the country.

9.3 PANCHAYATI RAJ INSTITUTIONS AND THE STATE FINANCE


COMMISSIONS—A REPORT

Mukesh P. Mathur

Self-governing village communities existed in India from an institution such as the Gram Panchayat to look after the
600 B.C. or even earlier. These village units were the points interests of the rural population at the grassroot level. The
of contact with higher authorities on matters affecting the Gram Panchayat was visualized as an implementing agency
village communities (Mathew, 2000). In the post- of the government-sponsored schemes and programmes for
independence period, the Balwantray Mehta Committee in orderly development of the rural areas of the country.
1959, first laid down the foundation of local self-government Rajasthan was the first state of the country to pass legislation
in the rural areas of the country. Based on Gandhian on Panchayati Raj Institutions (PRIs), and by 1959, all the
philosophy, this committee emphasized the strong need for states passed Panchayat Acts (Mathew, 2000).
248 India Infrastructure Report 2003

Over the years, however, the local-level governments, Panchayat at the village level; (2) Panchayat Samiti at the
especially at the village level, weakened considerably due intermediate (block/tehsil/mandal/taluk) level; and (3) Zila
to the withdrawal of traditional legitimate local functions Parishad or District Panchayat at the district level.
and a mismatch between the sources of revenue and even All the states have passed legislations in conformity with
the residual local functions. Large numbers of local bodies the 73rd CAA with a view to establishing a three-tier system
were superseded, sometimes for periods in excess of a of panchayats. All the three levels of panchayats have directly
decade. These village bodies failed to function as vibrant elected members with reservation for SCs, STs, backward
units of local self-government. Much of the explanation for classes, and women both at the membership level and the
their failure lies in the policy and defining framework executive level. The executive heads of panchayats are
which did not allow adequate space for their existence. The designated as presidents elected indirectly by the members
weakening of local bodies in terms of function, finances of the respective panchayats. The local MLAs/MLCs/MPs
and institutional capabilities would have contributed to the are also given membership with voting rights in the Zila
poor quality and inadequate levels of services in rural Parishad and the Panchayat Samiti. According to the
habitats9. amended Karnataka Panchayati Raj Act of 1993, one-fifth
But that situation changed in 1992 with the path-breaking of the village panchayat presidents are to be made ex
73th Constitutional Amendment Act (CAA) on panchayats. officio members of the Panchyat Samitis. The chief executive
Similarly, the passage of the 74th CAA on municipalities officer, executive officer and secretary, at these three levels
the same year changed the constitutional position of urban of local governance, provide the administrative support to
local bodies (ULBs). These path-breaking Acts have provided the panchayats. The panchayats have the responsibility of
a new dimension to fiscal federalism and decentralized public preparing local development plans at their respective levels
finance in the country’s federal system. In addition to ensuring and implementing them, for which they have to mobilize
constitutional validity to local bodies, these legislations have their own resources in addition to the resources devolved
also broadened the range of powers and functions of local to them from the state governments and the central
governments. The provisions that concern the constitution government.
of State Finance Commissions (SFCs) aim to rationalize The first round of elections for PRIs and ULBs has been
state–local fiscal relations. held in most states. A sizeable number of elected
The new fiscal arrangement has also affected a major representatives (approximately 2,60,000 to PRIs and over
change in the scope of the tasks of the Central Finance 60,000 to ULBs) including women and scheduled castes/
Commission (CFC), which, until the insertion of item (3– scheduled tribes, have been elected and bear responsibility
C) to the Article 280, was confined to the distribution of for taking decisions and giving voice to the needs of the
divisible taxes between the union and the states and grants- people.
in-aid to states under Article 275 of the Constitution. The As on May 1998, there are 2,34,078 PRIs in the
CFC now has also to suggest measures needed to augment country, classified into three categories of Gram Panchayats
the consolidated fund of a state to supplement the resources (2,27,698), Panchayat Samitis (5906), and Zila Parishads
of the local bodies on the basis of recommendations made (474). In some of the states rural local bodies are designated
by the SFC. Thus there is a positive departure in the state– as the ‘traditional councils’. These are Meghalaya, Mizoram
local fiscal relations from the earlier practices when the and Nagaland (Table 9.3.1).
system had been ad hoc. It is expected that recommendations
of SFCs as well as of the Eleventh Central Finance
FINANCES OF PRIS
Commission (EFC) would set norms, conventions and
practices relating to fiscal federalism and efficient local The finances of the panchayats consist of: (i) Own sources,
governance in the country. that is, taxes assigned by the state panchayat acts to the local
All the states of the Indian Union have amended their bodies concerned and levied and collected by them. Own
legislations both for panchayats and municipalities to confer sources also include non-tax revenues such as fee and fines,
to the provisions of the 73rd and 74th CAAs. user charges for services rendered, rent from the properties,
etc.; (ii) Shared taxes, that is, are collected by the states with
PANCHAYATI RAJ INSTITUTIONS TODAY a share of the proceeds being disbursed among the local
bodies of the state; and (iii) grants from the state/central
The 73rd CAA provides a three-tier structure to these government which may be either tied or untied. In some
institutions across the country viz; (1) Gram/Village states, certain taxes are statutorily assigned to the local
bodies but collected by their respective state governments
9 The situation with regard to urban bodies was no different. and made over to local bodies. For example, the surcharge
Rural Infrastructure 249

Table 9.3.1 to the first and second tiers of panchayats that is, zila
Panchayati Raj Institutions in India: As on May 1998 parishads (ZP) and taluk panchayats/panchayat samitis (TP/
PS). In cases where powers to levy taxes, fee and user
State/UT Grams Panchayat Zila All
Panchayats Samitis Parishads charges have also been given to ZP or PS, these are being
collected by the village panchayats and then transferred to
Andhra Pradesh 21943 1098 22 23063 the concerned local bodies. Usually, the taxes and charges
Arunachal Pradesh 2112 79 12 2103
levied by the ZP and PS are in the form of surcharge on
Assam 2489 202 21 2712
Bihar 12181 725 55 12961
the taxes and user charges levied by the village panchayats.
Goa 183 – 2 185 The finances of PRIs are presented in Tables 9.3.3 to
Gujarat 13316 184 19 13519 9.3.7. Panchayats are heavily dependent on the state
Haryana 5958 110 16 6084 government to finance their local activities. Income from
Himachal Pradesh 2922 72 12 3006 ‘other sources’ that primarily consist of transfers from the
Jammu and 2683 – 14 2697 state government that is, grants-in-aid and shared taxes,
Kashmir form an important part of the total revenue receipts of all
Karnataka 5675 175 20 5870 the three tiers of PRIs in most states. The dependence of
Kerala 991 152 14 1157
Panchayat Samitis (Taluka Panchayats) and District
Madhya Pradesh 30992 459 45 31426
Maharashtra 27619 319 29 27967 Panchayats on transfers is almost total.
Manipur 166 – 3 169 Whereas ULBs are generating, on an average, more
Mizoram – Traditional – – than 80 per cent of their revenue incomes from their own
Councils sources, this proportion is less than even five per cent in
Meghalaya – Traditional – – PRIs. The dependency ratio of PRIs on state governments
Councils varies significantly across states. PRIs of Bihar and Manipur
Nagaland – Traditional – – ‘function’ entirely on government grants. The local bodies
Councils of Haryana generate a substantial amount of revenue from
Orissa 5261 314 30 5605
their own sources, especially by tapping the non-tax
Punjab 11591 138 17 11746
Rajasthan 9185 237 31 9453 resources of their income (62.20 per cent).
Sikkim 148 – 4 152 Tables 9.3.5 and 9.3.6 show that fiscal transfer from
Tamil Nadu 12584 384 28 12996 the states to panchayats have gone up substantially during
Tripura 525 16 3 544 the last eight years for which the data is available. In per
Uttar Pradesh 58605 901 68 59574 capita terms, the transfers have gone up from less than Rs
West Bengal 3314 341 17 3672 100 in 1990–1 to more than Rs 250 in 1997–8. It is
A & N Islands 67 – 1 68 striking that although the share of tax income to total
Chandigarh – – – – income declined significantly over the years, non-tax
Dadra & Nagar 11 – 1 12
revenues have maintained their status in the finances of
Haveli
Daman & Diu 10 - 2 12 local bodies. In fact they have recorded a sharp increase
NCT Delhi – – – – of over 12.5 per cent per annum during the reference
Lakshadweep 10 – 1 11 years. User charges and land based non-property taxes,
Pondicherry 10 – 1 11 such as revenue from commercial properties and
All 227698 5906 474 234078 development of rural housing and entertainment schemes,
Source: Mathur, O.P. (2000); Decentralization in India–A Report, are some of the promising areas for resource generation
UMP–Asia Occasional Paper No. 47, Asian Institute of Technology, from the non-tax sector. Transfers from the state have
Klong Luang, Thailand. increased at the highest rate. The revenue at 16.6 per cent
has more than kept pace with inflation and population
on duty of transfer of property is collected by the growth, so that PRIs are in a better position than what
Government of Kerala, and after deducting the cost of they were in the 1980s. The tax revenues, though, have
collection is transferred to the local bodies of the state. grown slower than they could have.
Panchayats also raise loans from the state governments and Abdul Aziz, presenting the case of Karnataka, concludes
other financial institutions primarily to finance their that the panchayats have survived primarily on the
developmental works. The resource structure of panchayats development grants provided by the state. There was hardly
is given in Table 9.3.2. any attempt to generate own resources (Aziz, 1998). John,
It is interesting that the state legislations, which empower Oommen in the case of Kerala, notices more or less similar
the three levels of PRIs, do not give any source of revenue trends. He, however, observed that the financial position
250 India Infrastructure Report 2003

Table 9.3.2
Major Sources of Income for Panchayats in India

Sources Major Components


Internal/Own sources
a. Tax revenue Building/house tax; taxes on profession, trade, callings and employment; pilgrim tax; tax on fair and
other entertainments; tax on advertisements; octroi on animals or goods or both brought for sale (was
prevalent in Gujarat and Rajasthan which was abolished recently); vehicle tax (bullock cart/ tractor etc.);
land tax (for non-agricultural use); special tax for special works such as construction and public works
b. Non–tax revenue Fee and user charges levied by the respective panchayats for the provision of services. Water rate, street
lighting fee, conservancy fee, street cleaning fee, drainage fee, sanitary fee for public latrines and urinals,
pilgrimage fee, fee on sale of cattle, cess on conversion of land use, fee/rent and charges for use of common
resources such as panchayats shelter, hospital/ dispensary, schools, gazing land, market and weekly
bazaars, etc.
External sources
a. Shared taxes Stamp duty (duty on transfer of property), land revenue, motor vehicle tax, entertainment tax, seignior
government age royalties, forest revenue, etc.
b. Grants from General purpose, specific purpose, untied funds for developmental purposes and grants in lieu of taxes
such as in lieu of octroi in Gujarat and Rajasthan.

of Gram Panchayats is stronger than the other two tiers of Many State Finance Commissions have recommended a
PRIs since the taxation powers lie only in the hands of the performance-based grants-in-aid system to local bodies. The
Gram Panchayats (Oommen, J., 1998). One possible danger Himachal Pradesh State Finance Commission, for example,
of the liberal provisions of grants-in-aid is that the efforts has recommended release of transfers contingent on local
of PRIs to mobilize their own resources could slacken. bodies collecting statutory levies (Mathur, M.P., 1999).

Table 9.3.3
Sources of Revenues of PRIs, 1997–8

State Total revenue Own sources (%) of total Transfers (%) of


(Rs in lakh) Tax Non-tax Both total revenue
Andhra Pradesh 100060 3.18 2.30 5.48 94.52
Assam 1550 22.13 0.20 22.33 77.67
Bihar 36596 Nil Nil Nil 100.00
Goa 1057 27.53 9.93 37.46 62.54
Gujarat 223254 1.39 0.42 1.81 98.19
Haryana 8522 5.28 56.92 62.20 37.80
Himachal Pradesh 2525 2.69 Nil 2.69 97.31
Karnataka 376807 0.69 0.11 0.80 99.20
Kerala 98277 8.91 1.17 10.08 89.92
Madhya Pradesh 177901 0.66 1.14 1.80 98.20
Maharashtra 330747 2.26 1.14 3.40 96.60
Manipur 35 Nil Nil Nil 100.00
Meghalaya 1752 0.27 17.76 18.03 81.97
Orissa 64002 0.72 0.37 1.09 98.91
Punjab 13541 0.51 39.27 39.78 60.22
Rajasthan 152021 N.A. N.A. 2.02 97.98
TamilNadu 42216 7.80 0.26 8.06 91.94
Uttar Pradesh 88324 0.98 4.30 5.28 94.72
West Bengal 48775 1.61 2.41 4.02 95.98
All India 1935554 1.94 1.55 3.49 96.51
Notes: N.A.: Not Available
Source: CFC (2000), Report of the Eleventh Finance Commission (2000–5), Govt. of India, Ministry of Finance, Department of
Economic Affairs, New Delhi.
Rural Infrastructure 251

Table 9.3.4
Dependency of PRIs on Higher Levels of Governments

Level of PRIs 1990–1 1994–5 1997–8


Total Revenue % Transfers Total Revenue % Transfers Total Revenue % Transfers CAGR 1997–8
Receipts from state Receipts from state Receipts from state over 1990–1
(Rs crore) and centre (Rs crore) and centre (Rs crore) and centre (% per annum)
Village Panchayats 1941 83.74 3797 89.69 5452 89.56 15.9
(Village level)
Panchayati Samitis 1680 98.98 2968 90.04 4305 99.20 14.4
(Intermediate level)
District Panchayats 2992 98.74 5388 98.86 9599 99..22 18.1
(District level) (220.81)
All Tiers 6613 94.41 11882 95.98 193556 96.51 16.6
Figures in brackets refer to per cent increase in transfers from the state, in absolute terms (base year: 1990–1).
Source: CFC (2000).

Among the various taxes, building/house tax is the most Spending Structure
common and stable source of income for the majority of
Expenditure on maintenance of the core services such as
village panchayats in the country. In Kerala, house/building
water supply, street lighting, sanitation, and roads accounted
tax constituted more than 50 per cent of the total receipts
for only 7.43 per cent of the total expenditure of the PRIs
from the taxes in 1993–4. The other important taxes are
in 1997–8. In absolute terms this amounted to Rs 1555
profession tax and entertainment tax (SFC, Kerala, 1996).
crore for 1997–8, which was a bare Rs 21 per person! This
There is much scope for improvement in the collection
is suggestive of inadequate maintenance.
of house taxes. Many state finance commissions have, in
their reports, given suggestions for improvement in property
tax assessment and its administration. Design and STATE FINANCE COMMISSIONS AND THEIR
construction of houses in the rural areas in states like Tamil RECOMMENDATIONS
Nadu, Andhra Pradesh, Kerala, Karnataka, Maharasthra,
Haryana, Punjab, etc., are in no way less impressive and The State Finance Commissions (SFCs), constituted as
fashionable than in urban areas. In most states, the per the provisions of the 73rd and 74th Amendments in
assessment cycle has not been followed and tax rates have the Constitution of India bore responsibility for examining
not been revised since long. Wherever properties are not only the revenue-sharing arrangements between the
taxed, the arrears of taxes are allowed to accumulate due state governments and local bodies, but the entire gamut
to sheer inefficiency of local authorities, which has a direct of issues concerning the assignment of taxes, transfers and
impact on the finance of the local bodies concerned. such other issues for improving the financial health of local

Table 9.3.5
Revenue Structure of Panchayati Raj Institutions (All tiers) in India, 1990–1 and 1997–8

Sources of Revenue 1990–1 1997–8


Amount % to total Amount % to total CAGR 1997–8
(Rs in lakh) (Rs in lakh) over 1990-1
(% per annum)
A. Own Sources
Tax 23850 3.60 37691 1.94 6.8
Non-tax 13186 1.99 30017 1.55 12.5
Sub-total (A) 37036 5.59 67708 3.49 9.0
B. Other Revenues
(Transfers from 624347 94.41 1867846 96.51 16.9
the state)
Total Revenue (A + B) 661383 100.00 1935554 100.00 16.6
252 India Infrastructure Report 2003

Table 9.3.6
Trends in PRI Finances (in Rs)

Year Per capita Revenue Receipts Per capita Revenue


Own sources Others (Transfers) All Expenditure
1990–1 5.89 99.30 105.19 113.68
1991–2 5.47 110.09 115.56 128.98
1992–3 5.60 132.74 138.34 147.32
1993–4 6.35 152.74 159.09 173.90
1994–5 6.98 166.52 173.50 189.88
1995–6 7.74 186.33 194.07 207.84
1996–7 8.45 217.89 226.34 241.39
1997–8 9.27 255.76 265.03 286.61
Source: CFC (2000).

bodies. They were to cover the basis and method for both Appendix 9.3.1 provides a brief summary of the
distribution of grants and taxes, and also the quantum. recommendations of the selected SFCs with reference to
They were also to cover the measures to improve the tax assignments, tax sharing and grants to PRIs. Finance
financial position of PRIs and ULBs. Commissions of many states also suggested some changes
The wide-ranging task entrusted to the SFCs as in the legislative and administrative spheres to strengthen
incorporated in Article 243 I and Y and the addition of the local government institutions. These are:
Article 243 G and W (11th and 12th Schedules) of the • A Finance Commission Cell should function in the
Constitution is a landmark development. It opened up a Finance Department of the state government after the
new opportunity to review and streamline the existing expiry of the SFC’s term to review the implementation of
state–local fiscal relations. its recommendations (Karnataka, Tamil Nadu and (Kerala).

Table 9.3.7
Revenue and Expenditure of Panchayati Raj Institutions (All Tiers) in India (Rs in lakh)

Selected States 1990–1 1994–5 1997–8 CAGR of 1997–8


over 1990–1 (% p.a)
Total Total Total Total Total Total Total Total
Receipts Expenditure Receipts Expenditure Receipts Expenditure Receipts Expenditure
Andhra Pradesh 100060 100034 158151 160403 251159 250359 14.1 14.0
Assam 301 213 371 3991 1550 4057 26.4 52.3
Bihar 359 13630 59164 92656 36596 66040 93.6 25.3
Goa 367 207 776 405 1057 763 16.3 20.5
Gujarat 101816 108097 149445 150919 223254 226881 11.9 11.2
Haryana 4629 6787 6156 10825 8522 14643 9.1 11.6
Himachal Pradesh 404 404 578 578 2525 2525 29.9 29.9
Karnataka 131443 125092 245746 199249 376807 369641 16.2 16.7
Kerala 9662 9874 19353 19453 98277 73056 39.3 33.1
Madhya Pradesh 23368 22643 30234 30266 177901 178530 33.6 34.3
Maharashtra 104520 144425 204688 319695 330747 458538 17.9 17.9
Manipur 34 93 73 165 35 209 0.4 12.3
Meghalaya 914 1179 989 1478 1752 2356 9.7 10.4
Orissa 17813 17813 39773 39773 64002 64002 20.0 20.0
Punjab 9746 9999 16616 15829 13541 15953 4.8 6.9
Rajasthan 75450 74292 108474 108886 152021 153738 10.5 10.9
Tamil Nadu 27950 21967 32605 26134 42216 49062 6.1 12.2
Uttar Pradesh 42931 43376 61371 61161 88324 90714 10.9 11.1
West Bengal 7220 12101 48771 53587 48775 55488 31.4 24.3
All India 661383 714690 1188298 1300495 1935554 2093116 16.6 16.6
Source: CFC (2000).
Rural Infrastructure 253

• Periodic service training for the local government of tax on sale of properties, the commission has suggested
employees to increase their efficiency (Karnataka, Punjab, that Zila Parishads may be empowered to levy a tax on the
Maharashtra, Tamil Nadu and Kerala). sale price of all immovable properties within the district,
• Establishment of a local development fund for where the price is Rs 25,000 or more at the rate of 1 per
subsidizing interest rates for non-remunerative but desirable cent. The Registration Department has to collect this tax.
service schemes (Kerala). Three per cent of the total collection should go to the state
• A Tax Valuation Committee to listen to the objections government as collection charges. Revenue from rural areas
of the taxpayer regarding PT assessment (Punjab). of the district is shared in equal proportion between the
• One common legislation for all local bodies to avoid Zila Parishads and Panchayat Samitis. The distribution of
confusion regarding the regulations and bye-laws (Karnataka, shared revenue among the panchayat samitis will be made
Kerala, Punjab and Uttar Pradesh). on the basis of their population as per the 1991 Census.
• Privatization for activities like maintenance of street The Rajasthan SFC also suggested interesting taxes, which
lights and roads and other core services (Kerala, Uttar could be levied by the village panchayats of the state. These
Pradesh, Punjab and Tamil Nadu). are: tax on dhabas, hotels, motels, automobile servicing and
• Privatization of the maintenance of commercial assets repair shops, petrol/diesel pumps, etc. situated on the
(Tamil Nadu). national/state highways in their respective jurisdictions.
• Public participation for the maintenance of services Transfers from the state to local bodies in the form of
(Maharashtra). revenue sharing and grants-in-aid play an important role
A close examination of some of the SFC reports show in the financial structure of local governments. This is
that these Finance Commissions have tried to rationalize more so in the case of rural local bodies. It is significant
the local tax structure by suggesting reforms in assessment that prior to the enactment of CAA, grants-in-aid have
and administration of taxes besides giving powers to local been the major component of fiscal transfers from the state
bodies. Finance Commissions of Kerala, Karnataka, Tamil to local bodies, and the share of state taxes and levies were
Nadu and Uttar Pradesh, for example, have recommended extremely low. SFCs constituted as per the provisions of
reform in property taxes and have suggested the ‘area based’ CAA have recommended sharing of state-level resources
or ‘site valuation’ system for assessment of property tax. A in addition to grants-in-aid to local bodies. Variations,
majority of SFCs also recommended autonomy to local however, have been noticed among different states in terms
bodies, particularly village panchayats (VPs) for fixing tax of scope of resources to be pooled and its sharing principles
rates and user charges. The West Bengal SFC has among the PRIs and ULBs. Whereas the Rajasthan, Tamil
recommended a new regime of tax collection in which tax Nadu, Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal Finance Commissions
administration works in close cooperation with panchayats recommended the devolution of a set percentage of the net
and gives a proportion of tax collection as entitlement to proceeds of only the tax revenues of the states, Andhra
these bodies. Pradesh has suggested for sharing of both from taxes and
The Kerala State Finance Commission (KSFC) emphasized non-taxes. The Karnataka SFC has adopted a different
the need to develop new sources of revenues besides suggesting mechanism by replacing the present system of sharing a
principles to rationalize the local tax structure. The Punjab portion of the specific taxes levied by the state government
State Finance Commission (PSFC) has recommended by a share in the ‘total non-tax gross own revenue receipts’.
autonomy to all the three tiers of PRIs to levy taxes and Table 9.3.8 brings out the relevant details of only those
fees, and also to fix the rates thereof, without the state states where SFCs have recommended the concept of
control that had been imposed following the Punjab ‘global sharing’ for transfer of state revenues. SFCs of other
Panchayati Raj Act of 1994 (Oommen, M.A., 1998). states have recommended sharing of only specific taxes or
Some of the new taxes suggested by the KSFC are: a tax awarded a fixed amount for PRIs and ULBs.
on sale of properties, central government properties, entry The SFCs of some states like Punjab and Kerala have
of transport vehicles10 carrying goods for local sale and suggested the sharing of only specific taxes with the local
consumption, cable TV operators, stamp duty on documents bodies of the states. The Punjab SFC, for instance,
to be submitted to local bodies and library cess. In case recommended transferring 20 per cent of the net proceeds
of the five major taxes to the local bodies. These are: stamp
10 Entry taxes fragment markets and the distortions they create duty, electricity duty, entertainment tax, entertainment tax
are very large, much larger than what their first order effects alone
on cinematography and motor vehicle tax. Distribution
would indicate. The process of growth and transformation in the UK
(the first industrial revolution) had the integration of the home among the PRIs and ULBs will be made on the basis of
market brought about by the abolition of local tolls and taxes as the following criteria: (1) Stamp duty—on the basis of
a necessary condition (Editor). directive principle; (2) Motor-vehicle tax—on the basis of
254 India Infrastructure Report 2003

Table 9.3.8
Recommended Share in State Resource Pool: SFC Award

State Per cent Ratio of PRIs and ULBs Basis of distribution


Net proceeds of state taxes:
Rajasthan 2.18 1.8 % and 1% Rural–urban population
Tamil Nadu 8.0 55% and 45% Not available
Uttar Pradesh 11.0 4% and 7% Population (80%); area (20%)
West Bengal 16.0 Break-up not available Population and % of SC/ST/non-literates
Tax and non–tax revenues:
Andhra Pradesh 39.24 70% and 30% Development criteria such as length of roads, etc.
Madhya Pradesh 2.91 85% and 15% Population, area, tax efforts
Tax revenues:
Assam 2.0 Not available Population
Non-tax revenue:
Karnataka 36.0 85% and 15% For panchayats—population, area literacy, no. of
beds, road length
Source: NIRD (2000), Background papers prepared for the National Workshop on Follow-up Measures by State Governments on
SFC Recommendations, organized by the State Finance Commission Cell, National Institute of Rural Development, Hyderabad,
3–4 October 2002.

proportionate length of roads maintained by the PRIs and Commissions. However, this issue has remained unsolved,
ULBs; (3) Electricity duty–on the basis of collections in and grants are still largely ad hoc and have varying basis.
PRIs and ULBs; (4) Entertainment tax—20 per cent share Although some of the SFCs have recommended tied,
of collections to PRIs and ULBs; (5) Entertainment tax on untied as well as performance-based incentive grants, the
cinematography—20 per cent share of collections to PRIs devolution mechanism between various levels of local
and ULBs. governments, both urban as well as rural, has not been
The mechanism of revenue sharing is marked by addressed properly. Only the Kerala State Finance
significant interstate variations. First, with pooling ad Commission has recommended grants, both for plan and
hocism would reduce and PRIs and ULBs could look non-plan activities, with a mechanism for their devolution
forward to more stable flows. Second, this system provides among different layers of local governments. In a sense,
some incentives for PRIs/ ULBs to use their own sources the Kerala Finance Commission has tried to bring in some
of revenues by using various tools of resource mobilization kind of rationality in the structure of grant-in-aid as also
and generation. Third, the buoyancy of state taxes and its mechanism for devolution. Appendix 9.3.1 gives a brief
levies will benefit the local bodies. State taxes grow as per overview of the key recommendations of the selected SFCs
the growth in the state economy, and the benefits of regarding grants-in-aid.
economic growth in the state will automatically be transferred
to the local bodies. THE ELEVENTH FINANCE COMMISSION
In case of grants-in-aid, usually there are three types of
grants: (i) general purpose, (ii) in lieu of taxes and (iii) As stated earlier, the Article 280 of the Constitution of
specific or conditional grants. The general-purpose grants India stands amended by the Constitution 73rd and 74th
provide local bodies with additional resources the autonomy Amendment Act of 1992, and a new clause has been inserted
to use them. The specific purpose or conditional grants, in it making it mandatory for the CFC to suggest measures
however, are to be used for specific service/programmes or needed to augment the consolidated fund of the state so as
may have some conditions for its use. Grants in lieu of taxes to supplement the resources of the local bodies in the state
are given as compensatory grants on account of the abolition on the basis of recommendations made by the SFC.
or withdrawal of certain taxes, such as octroi, in Madhya The CFC has recommended grants amounting to Rs
Pradesh, Uttar Pradesh, Karnataka, etc. 10,000 crore for local bodies of the states during 2000–
Grants sometimes provide for matching provisions and, 5. Of this, Rs 1600 crore are for the panchayats and Rs
like other transfers, can help local bodies to address the 400 crore are for the municipalities for each of the five
mis-match between the local resources and their years, starting from the financial year 2000–1. In per capita
responsibilities. Rationalization of the grants-in-aid system terms, the amount recommended for the PRIs is higher
was one of the primary objectives of the first State Finance than that for the ULBs. This amount will be over and above
Rural Infrastructure 255

the normal flow of funds to the local bodies from the states The Rs 8000 crore recommended for devolution to
and the amount that would flow from the implementation PRIs may still be inadequate! According to an NIRD study
of SFC recommendations (CFC, 2000). conducted for the Eleventh Finance Commission, it is
These grants are to be utilized exclusively for the estimated that PRIs will require more than Rs 142,000
maintenance of civic services in the rural and urban areas crore for a period of five years for O&M of core services
and will be distributed among the local bodies of the state alone in the rural areas of the country. In addition,
on the basis of the principles recommended by the SFC. approximately Rs 84,000 crore will be needed to augment
The grants are to be untied on condition that they are not the basic infrastructure and services in rural India (CFC,
used for payment of salaries and wages. The CFC has also 2000)11.
suggested the levy of a profession tax, rationalization of Significantly, the term period of the Eleventh Finance
property/house tax, the levy of a substitute for octori and Commission did not coincide in most cases with the tenure
an efficient system of user charges. The CFC has also of the first SFCs. As a consequence, the recommendations
recommended the levy of surcharge/cess on state taxes and of the CFC and the SFCs were not for the same period
the delegation of power to PRIs to levy land tax. They also leading to problems in allocation of the grants.
emphasized a need for improvements in budgetary and
accounting systems besides capacity building of local
MAJOR SHORTCOMINGS
governments in various fields of local administration and
management. When the first generation SFCs were constituted, it was
The CFC has recommended a special grant of Rs. 200 expected that the state governments would follow a tradition
crore for development of database on the finances of the of accepting the recommendations of the SFCs as in the case
PRIs and ULBs and Rs 98.61 crore for maintenance of of the CFCs. But that did not happen. Action-taken reports
accounts. The criteria recommended by the CFC for of some of the states show that the state governments have
distribution of grants to the PRIs and ULBs have been not accepted all the recommendations made by the finance
shown in Table 9.3.9. commissions. The Andhra Pradesh SFC, for example, made
The Government of India has accepted the 84 recommendations on financial as well as non- financial
recommendations of the Eleventh Finance Commission matters. Of these, the government accepted only 60—that,
subject to the following conditions (CFC, 2000): too, in principle—and these are yet to be implemented.
1. The local bodies should be required to raise suitable Even the recommendation concerning transfer of 39.24 per
matching resources; cent of tax and non-tax revenues of the state to the local
2. In case where elected local bodies are not in place, bodies has not been accepted in its true sense. Although the
the central government shall hold the share of such bodies concept of a fixed percentage of global sharing was accepted
in trust on a non-lapsable basis during 2000–5. The central in principle no specific percentage has been fixed. In Tamil
government may also similarly hold back a part of the Nadu, of the total 413 recommendations made by the SFC,
recommended share in case of such bodies to whom functions only 244 have been accepted by the state government. The
and responsibilities have not been devolved; report of the Maharashtra Finance Commission contains
3. Earmarking of funds for maintenance of accounts, nearly 129 recommendations on various matters pertaining
within the overall recommended level of grants, may be to PRI finances. Of the twenty-seven total recommendations
increased to the extent necessary in consultation with the made on devolution of grants and taxes to PRIs by the
CAG; and commission, the state government has accepted only twelve
4. Measures to strengthen accounts and audit of local recommendations fully. Whereas eleven recommendations
bodies have been accepted in principle. Details will be were accepted partially, four was rejected by the government.
worked out in consultation with the CAG. Share in profession tax was one of the recommendations
which was rejected by the state government.
Table 9.3.9
CFC Criteria for Distribution of Grants to PRIs and ULBs 11 This works out to around Rs 400 per person as maintenance
expenditure per year. The total expenditure of panchayats per person
Indicator Weight age was just about Rs 286 per annum. In addition the estimated capital
(%) expenditure is itself about Rs 1200 per person. The gross capital
formation (GCF) in the private sector in 2000–1 was about Rs
Population 40
91,000 crore, and in the public sector about the same. Thus, these
Index of decentralization 20
figures imply a 15 per cent to 20 per cent share of public sector GCF.
Distance from higher per capita income 20
Clearly, these estimates are highly unrealistic and are reflective of
Revenue effort 10 needs, rather than being demand based, or based on what is possible
Geographical area 10 at this stage of development. (Editor).
256 India Infrastructure Report 2003

CONCLUSIONS 4. PRIs could privatize certain services. The state


governments should prepare necessary guidelines and
1. Although the Constitution Amendment Act provides legislation in this regard. Frameworks for the active
full autonomy to the PRIs, the state level functionaries cooperation of the local population in the provision of
are hesitant to handing over the financial and functional basic services such as water supply, sanitation, education,
powers to these local governments. The CAA are also health, need to be explored. Further, there could be a code
silent on issues concerning financial devolution to PRIs of ethics for officials and non-officials of PRIs.
in line with functional devolution as provided in the 5. The major problem among the rural local bodies
Eleventh Schedule. Had the CAA given direct financial is the lack of expertise. Thus there is a need for capacity
powers to PRIs commensurate with the functions building and training of local officials, particularly with
assigned to them, real autonomy at the local level, would reference to taking up the challenge offered by the new
also have been possible. It could have also made these functions assigned to them under the eleventh schedule.
local bodies more responsible and accountable to people’s 6. National Infrastructure Development Fund (NIDF)
needs. could be established to extend loans and financial aid to
2. House tax is one of the main sources of income for both PRIs and ULBs for infrastructure development.
the PRIs. This should be simplified and rationalized. 7. The central government, as a facilitator of change,
Exemptions from property tax should be minimized. Taxes has a special role. Through its administrative ministry, that
which are local in nature, such as, entertainment tax, is the Ministry of Rural Development, it should ensure the
professional tax, stamp duty, land revenue, etc. should timely and effective action by the state governments on the
either be transferred to panchayats or a reasonable share recommendations of SFCs. The Ministry of Rural
of it be given to these local bodies. Development could also introduce schemes akin to the
3. PRIs should be given autonomy to fix tax rates and Ministry of Urban Development’s City Challenge Fund
user charges as in the case of Punjab. and Urban Reforms Incentive Fund for PRIs.

APPENDIX 9.3.1
Key Recommendations of the First State Finance Commissions on Financial Devolution to PRIs in Selected States
KERALA
Tax Assignments
Gram Panchayats (GPs):
a. Tax on Buildings
• Building tax to be exclusively assigned to Gram Panchayats in the range of 6–10% of annual rental value.
• ARV should be replaced by tax, based on the plinth area.
• Minimum tax payable may be fixed at Rs 15 and classification of buildings based on the basis of quality of construction,
age, etc.
• Charging interest @2% per month on arrears.
• Other suggestions for rationalization of Property Tax.
b. Advertisement Tax On
Government may fix the minimum rate chargeable and leave it to panchayats to fix it above those rates (New).
c. Tax on Land
• Land tax may be doubled (from 50 paise to Re 1)
• 60% of the collection may go to block panchayats and the balance to district panchayats.
• Irrespective of the size of the holding minimum land tax may be fixed at Rs 5 per year in panchayat areas.
• Portion of income from the sale of court fee stamps may be earmarked to local bodies (LBs).
d. Tax on Entertainment
• Entertainment tax and additional entertainment tax should be merged into a single item.
• The difference between show tax and surcharge on show tax may be abolished and merged into one.
e. Tax on Professions
• Profession tax in the case of persons other than salary and wage earners may be levied at the rates recommended.
• The rates of profession tax may be uniform in urban and rural LBs and that the number of slabs be reduced to ten from
earlier sixteen in case of PRIs and fourteen in municipalities, and the rates should be rationalized.
f. Land Cess
• Collection of a tax on the sale of land from owners at the time of sale.
Rural Infrastructure 257

Panchayat Samitis (PSs):


Not assigned any taxes as per the Conformity Act.
Zila Parishads (ZPs):
Not assigned any taxes as per the Conformity Act.
Revenue Sharing
Land Tax
60% of additional income from Land Tax may go to block Panchayat and the balance to District Panchayat.
Building Exemption Fee
50% of the building exemption fee.
Stamp Duty
25% of surcharge.
Grants
Devolution of Plan Grants
Devolution of plan grants of state to LBs. The SFC has endorsed the existing pattern as followed by the State Planning Board.
• Population in 1991 census—70%
• Population of SC/ST in 1991 census —10%
• Total workers excluding workers in manufacturing processing, servicing & repairs outside household industry—10%
• Proportion of agriculture workers —10%.
Total—100%
Distribution of Rural Pool
• Population in 1991 census—75%
• Population of SC/ST in 1991 census—5%
• Financial needs of LBs—15%
Financial needs of the LBs is assessed on the basis of income classification ranging from lowest income (getting less than Rs 5
lakh p.a.) to highest income category (getting more than Rs 20 lakh p.a.) Kerala SFC has classified such four groups of panchayats.
Income for this purpose includes income from all sources including motor vehicle tax and loans.
Tax efforts of LBs–5% Tax efforts are judged by two indicators:
• The percentage of collection to demand
• The rate at which property tax is being levied.
Intra-District Allocation
Following is the State Planning Board’s formula, which has been followed for intra-district allocation:
• GPs—55.80%
• PSs—14.33%
• ZPs—14.93%
Types of Grants
• New plan grants for development projects
• Old plan grants prior to 1994—untied plan funds given to LBs.
• General purpose grants—Non- Statutory Non-Plan Grants:
1% of the state revenue is assigned for general-purpose grant. This 1% has to be distributed between ULBs and PRIs on
the basis of population
• Maintenance grants for building of schools and hospitals, should be related to the current cost of construction.

PUNJAB
Tax Assignments
Gram Panchayats
• Total land revenue should be assigned to the GPs.
• Mandatory tax on professions, individuals, traders, commission agents and shopkeepers based on income slabs to be levied by
GPs (new).
• GPs to levy tax on advertisement and hoardings (new).
• GPs to tax brick kilns, rice sellers, stone crushers, petrol pumps, poultry farms, dairy units, stud farms, fish farms, and small
and large scale industries in the rural areas (new).
• GPs to charge fee @ 2% of the value of goods sold from sellers where markets are held (new).
• GPs to charge parchi fee from buses @Rs 5 to Rs 10 where they provide certain facilities (new).
258 India Infrastructure Report 2003

House tax
• No tax on kutcha houses. Below 10 marla houses and houses of yellowcard holders.
• House tax on pucca houses at the rate not below Rs 100 p.a. (new)
Panchayat Samitis
• 10% Auction money on Punjab medium liquor vends and 20% excise duty on Indian made foreign liquor should be the
share of PSs and GPs. The share in 50:50. GPs should get their individual share on population basis.
Zila Parishad
• Land revenue cess, levied should be assigned to the PRIs. If ZPs pass a resolution for levying the cess on land revenue the state
should levy, collect and then transfer to PRIs at the rate of GPs—50%, PSs—30%, ZPs—20%.
• ZPs can levy a tax on the sale of immovable properties within the district at the rate of 1% of the sale price.
• Registration fee in cattle fairs raised from Rs 2 to Rs 5 per cattle. The management of cattle fairs be transferred to ZPs along
with assets. (new)
Revenue Sharing
Transfer of revenues of five taxes now collected by state government to local bodies (Stamp duty, motor vehicles tax, electricity duty,
entertainment tax and entertainment tax on cinematograph) 20% of the net proceeds of these five taxes.
General principles:
• Buoyant and elastic taxes.
• Proportion of sharing on the basis of fiscal needs.
• To enhance autonomy, unconditional transfer with in-built provision for incentives.
Sharing between ULBs and PRIs
On the basis of % of collection from PRIs and ULBs
• Stamp-duty: on the basis of derivative principle
• Punjab motor vehicle tax: On the basis of proportionate length of roads maintained by the ULBs/ PRIs.
• Electricity duty: On the basis of collection
• Entertainment tax: 20% share
Inter-tier Distribution
• GPs—50%
• PSs—30%
• ZPs—20%
Distribution amongst GPs, PSs and ZPs
• On the basis of population
Grants
Per Capita Grant
• to be given to weak GPs having a per capita income of less than Rs 100 to bring their income up to Rs 100
Rs 18 crore. For the five years from 1995–2000. No part of it should be utilized on salaries and wages.
Payment of 50% electricity charges for street lighting to weak GPs
Varies between 25% and 50% of the total electricity bill to be divided by the department on merit.
Incentive grants
For good performing PRIs.
• GPs—Rs 0.50 lakh
• PSs—Rs 1.00 lakh for 1995–2000
No incentive grant is suggested for ZPs.
Remark: The commission recommends only two types of grants viz. general-purpose grant and specific-purpose grant.

WEST BENGAL
Tax Assignments
Gram Panchayats
Water rate, lighting rate, conservancy rate.
Panchayat Samitis
• Water rate and lighting rate
Zila Parishad
Water rate and lighting rate:
Rural Infrastructure 259

Collection of irrigation rates and the related responsibility of supplying water and routine maintenance should be handed over
to ZPs, having jurisdiction over such projects. The raised resources may be distributed proportionally to the collection efforts of
individual LBs within a district.
• Taxes on entertainment now collected by the state should be handed over to local bodies.
• Resources generated in the regulated markets should be brought within the purview of DPCs & the net proceeds ploughed
back in the market hinterlands.
• All taxes collected from all districts will go to the state kitty and distribution will start from there following the entitlement
ratios as provided in the revenue sharing.
Tax Sharing
• Tax sharing is considered an entitlement to be used for plan and non-plan purposes.
• Funds to be spent according to priorities set by each local body in its development plan.
16% of the net proceeds to all tax collected by the state in a year should be transferred to LBs.
Li – 0.5, Dli + 0.1
(D2i + D3i + D4i + D5i + D6i)
Where li – total percentage allocation for district ‘i’.
• Dli – Proportion of population of the district i to the total population of the district (weight 50%). The rest of the 50%
weight is assigned to degree of backwardness viz.
• Illiteracy level of the district (10%)
• SC/ST and Muslim population (10%)
• Area of the district (10%)
• Rural population of the district (10%)
• Inverse ratio of per capita Bank Deposits (10%)
Intra-District Allocation:
• District Panchayat Fund = D.P./100. Where P=% of Panchayat population to total population. D=98% of the total
entitlements. 2% is kept for funding incentive schemes.
PRIs allocation
ZPs—30%
PSs—20%
GPs—50%
Entitlement for GPs
Population—50%
Percentage d of SC/ST—25%
Percentage of illiterates—25%
Entitlement for PSs
Population – 50%
Percentage SC/ST—25%
Percentage of illiterates—25%
Entitlement for ZPs
30% of the district panchyat fund i.e. DP/100
Grants
The commission has not discussed much about grants in its report
The total district plan fund is divided into following:
• Grants
• Entitlements going to districts
Plan grants may follow the distribution pattern of entitlements explained. A large number of centrally-sponsored schemes such
as JRY, IRDP, etc. are now in operation in which the central releases have to be matched by proportionate state resources. Such state
and central releases would continue to be grants and will not be part of the untied entitlement of the LBs concerned.
Source: Compiled from the Reports of First State Finance Commissions, Kerala, Punjab and West Bengal.
260 India Infrastructure Report 2003

9.4 THE RURAL INFRASTRUCTURE DEVELOPMENT FUND: A REVIEW

Alice Albin Morris • Sebastian Morris

THE RURAL INFRASTRUCTURE DEVELOPMENT PRIs/SHGs/NGOs


FUND In 1995–6 state governments/state-owned corporations
were the institutions eligible to avail of the fund. In 1999–
The Government of India announced in the 1995–6 Budget
2000 there was a major policy change. Rural infrastructure
the setting up of the Rural Infrastructure Development
projects through Panchayati Raj Institutions/Self-Help
Fund (RIDF) to be operated through the National Bank
Groups /Non Government Organizations (PRIs/SHGs/
for Agriculture and Rural Development (NABARD) for
NGOs) from RIDF were allowed12. To facilitate village
financing ongoing rural infrastructure projects. The fund
level infrastructure implemented by PRIs/SHGs/NGOs
was to be made up of contributions from Indian scheduled
the list of the eligible purposes was extended to cover
commercial banks against their shortfall in agricultural
activities like rural links/culverts/small bridges, community
lending up to an extent of 1.5 per cent of net bank credit.
irrigation including indigenous systems like bandhara,
The initial corpus for RIDF-I was Rs 2000 crore. This
primary school building, primary health service, village
was utilized for extending loans to state governments
haat, cold storage, godowns, and seed farms. To date,
mainly for incomplete irrigation projects.) The successive
though only Rs 1737.77 crore out of a total of Rs 16,835.57
union budgets have enhanced the corpus. In 2001–2 the
crore, that is 10.32 per cent (RIDF-V to VII) had been
corpus was Rs 5000 crore. The total corpus allocated for
lent to projects spearheaded by PRIs /SHGs /NGOs.
RIDF aggregated to Rs 23,000 crore. The outlay for
RIDF–VIII in the budget presented for 2002–3 is Rs
NABARD’s Appraisal
5500 crore. Apart from financing incomplete projects the
NABARD, since 1996–7, has been providing, under the All loans sanctioned from the fund are project-based. The
RIDF funding, for new infrastructure initiatives. The project proposals received from the state governments are
loans are guaranteed by the state government, except in appraised for technical feasibility, financial viability, and
the case of certain projects, where NGOs, ‘self -help economic and social benefits. A Project Sanctioning
groups’, and Panchayati Raj Institutions (PRIs) have taken Committee (PAC) sanctions the projects, which is a sub-
the initiative. committee of the Board of Directors of NABARD. In terms
Ongoing and new projects with a gestation period of 2– of numbers medium and minor irrigation project accounts
3 years are given priority .The rate of interest was 13 per for majority of the projects sanctioned. In terms of amount,
cent in 1995–6. It was lowered to 12 per cent in RIDF– rural roads and bridges have the highest share. Over the
II and V. It was further reduced to 11.5 per cent in RIDF- years there has been an increase in number and amount
VI and 10.5 per cent in RIDF-VII. The Budget for 2002–3 sanctioned for projects other than irrigation, rural bridges
has announced that the interest rate for RIDF-VIII will be and roads.
linked to the bank rate. The interest currently stands at 8.5 12 In projects to be implemented by PRI/SHG/NGO if the state
per cent. The ceiling on loan amount was 50 per cent of
government borrows for PRIs/SHGs/NGOs then the bank takes
updated/revised cost of the project in 1995–6 but has been additional guarantees. Where the state government desires that the
increased to 90 per cent in the subsequent years. The maturity PRI/SHG/NGO apart from implementing the project should also be
period for deposits/ advances was 5 years till 1998–9 (RIDF- the borrowers the loan is released on execution of a default guarantee
IV). This has been liberalized to 7 years since RIDF-V in by the state government in favour of the bank along with the usual
1999–2000. mandate. In case NABARD is satisfied that (i) the project to be
financed are likely to generate adequate income to enable the PRI/
Initially the fund was available for implementing medium/
SHG/NGO to repay the interest and the principle on time without
minor irrigation projects, soil conservation, rural roads, default, (ii) PRI/SHG/NGO are financially, managerially and
bridges, energization of state-owned tube wells and rural organizationally capable of managing the project and (iii) PRI/SHG/
market yards. Later inland waterways, integrated rural market NGO has power to create assets and charge on its assets/ income in
yards, integrated rural cold chains with support facilities, favour of the lender the national bank will waive the requirement of
construction of fish jetties, rural godowns were added. In security and may favour making alternative arrangement.
The NABARD has constituted State/ District Level Sanctioning
RIDF-VI mini hydro and system improvement projects
Committees depending on the flow of proposals from PRIs/ SHGs/
under the power sector and citizen’s information centres and NGOs to expedite the sanctioning process of SHG/PRI/NGO initiated
projects within the IT sector were also covered. projects.
Rural Infrastructure 261

Table 9.4.1
Loan Disbursements Under the RIDF Tranches, and Deposits Received from Commercial Banks

Year RIDF-I RIDF-II RIDF-III RIDF-IV RIDF-V RIDF-VI RIDF-VII Disbur- Growth Deposits Growth
sement rate of received rate in
during disburse- from deposits
the year ments banks (per
on all (per cent cent per
RIDFs per annum) annum)
1995–6 387.3 – – – – – – 387.3 – 350.0 –
1996–7 795.5 291.6 – – – – – 1087.1 180.7 1042.3 197.8
1997–8 250.1 542.2 216.7 – – – – 1009.0 -7.2 1007.0 n
1998–9 109.2 602.6 469.1 132.3 – – – 1313.1 30.1 1338.0 32.9
1999–2000 149.3 440.5 726.8 543.3 418.0 – – 2277.9 73.5 2306.6 72.4
2000–01 51.0 215.5 472.7 706.7 771.4 959.6 – 3176.9 39.5 2653.6 15.0
2001–02 18.3 157.5 297.9 480.8 779.9 939.5 1116.6 3790.4 19.3 3590.7 35.3
Total 1760.7 2249.9 2183.1 1863.0 1969.3 1899.1 1116.6 13041.7 – 12288.3 –

The aggregate amount disbursements under RIDF -I to Completion Still Awaited


VII till 31 March 2002 stood at Rs 13,041.66 crore. Details
The completion status of projects from RIDF-I to IV
of disbursement are given in the Table 9.4.1. The deposit
(which should have been completed by end-2002, as per
outstanding received from banks at the end of March 2002
the project plans, is shown in Table 9.4.3. Only about 71
was Rs 9725.02 crore. Repayments were being received
per cent of the projects had been completed. Larger projects
regularly from the state governments by the NABARD.
especially in irrigation show poorer completion. Thus, it
is certain that the size-weighted completion status is much
Large Time Overruns
worse than what Table 9.4.3 would indicate. Irrigation and
Projects showed considerable time overruns the reasons rural roads and bridges dominate. Table 9.4.4 brings out
for which according to the NABARD, were: (1) Mismatch the average size of projects, which could lend support our
between physical and financial disbursements; (2) The claim that the size-weighted delays have been large.
implementing departments (of governments) were not Unfortunately, for irrigation projects there is no break up
adequately funded by the state governments; (3) The projects into minor, major and medium. Table 9.4.5 brings out the
also faced problems of land acquisition, forest and purpose-wise loans under all RIDFs.
environmental clearance; (4) Inadequate monitoring and
inability to take corrective action by government officers
also delayed the project, (5) Lack of transparency among
A COMMENTARY
the key functionaries also led to delays in the completion Macroeconomic Compulsion
of the projects.
Based on the Project Completion Reports (PCRs) Public investments in agriculture had been slowing down
received from the state governments, the NABARD in the 1980s and there was much concern that the pace
observed that much irrigation, potential, employment of agricultural output would not be maintained. In the early
growth, and value added had taken place. Some of the 1990s the economy underwent stabilization and then
salient features along with memo items are presented in structural adjustment. Public investments bore the brunt of
Table 9.4.2. Furthermore, the irrigation potential created the expenditure reduction policies that were put in place
by the projects was 16.67 lakh hectares. Utilization of to bring the fiscal deficit in line. In the first flush the centre
irrigation on an average was 68 per cent. Incremental did most of the adjustment. Soon enough part of the burden
incomes from the project ranged from Rs 7000 to 9000 of adjustment fell on the states as the grants and loans from
per hectare. The projects were financially viable with a the centre that supported capital expenditures slowed down.
financial rate of return (FRR) ranging from 13 to 50 per More importantly, the simultaneous pursuit of financial
cent. The social returns in these are known to be very high, sector reform along with the real sector reform that raised
and as such the focus on these activities of physical interest rates, meant that state governments were suddenly
infrastructure is most laudable. stressed/extended on their debt service. Their borrowings
262 India Infrastructure Report 2003

Table 9.4.2
A Summary of ‘Benefits’ and Effects of Irrigation, and Roads and Bridges Projects under RIDF
RIDF-I RIDF-II RIDF-III RIDF-IV RIDF-V RIDF-VI RIDF-VII
1995–6 1996–7 1997–8 1998–9 1999–2000 2000–1 2001–2
Estimated GDP generated in irrigation 1.45 0.74 0.78 0.81 1.14 0.69 0.60
projects / Outlay on RIDF
Average output to net fixed capital in 0.76 0.83 0.79 0.84 0.83
agriculture (NAS)
GFCF in agriculture (Rs cr) 20739 23086 24608 23785 31717 28425.5 29720.3
GFCF in electricity gas and 23826 27971 29423 33160 37835 35200 39700
water (Rs cr)
GFCF in construction (Rs cr) 5665 3189 6855 6029 6455 6400 6200
RIDF outlay on irrigation as per cent 8.66 5.43 3.88 3.59 3.32 4.31 4.02
of GFCF in agriculture
RIDF outlay on roads and bridges 0.50 39.40 23.30 32.75 35.88 40.91 39.52
as per cent of GFCF in construction
GCF by the Public Sector in 6762 7296 6921 7549
Agriculture (NAS)
RIDF outlay on irrigation as per cent 26.56 17.20 13.78 11.30
of GCF in agriculture in public sector
NNP per capita (NAS) (Rs) 10160 11601 12772 14712 16047 16487 17789
Surplus share in NNP per capita (NAS) 0.17 0.17 0.16 0.16 0.16 0.16 0.16
Imputed wage and mixed Income (Rs) 8463 9664 10716 12358 13479 13849 14943
RIDF created employment due to 6.62 2.21 1.59 2.35 14.30 7.88 1.92
irrigation projects (recurring) (lakh)
RIDF created employment* due to 1.12 0.52 0.20 0.34 0.30 0.40 0.33
irrigation projects (non-recurring) (lakh)
RIDF created total employment due to 7.74 2.73 1.79 2.69 14.60 8.28 2.25
irrigation projects (lakh)
RIDF outlay per unit employment 23196 45873 53169 31696 7211 14809 53175
created by irrigation projects (Rs)
Note: For comparison and ratios the NAS (National Accounts Statistics) figures for the start of RIDF year is used. GCF—gross capital
formation; GFCF—gross fixed capital formation.

went up sharply so did the debt service burdens13. The credit flows to these ‘priority’ sectors, the government
RIDF was announced by the centre as a way to support continued with the policy. But it allowed banks not meeting
the states in the rural, especially agricultural, capital forming
investments, without the centre having to fund the same. Table 9.4.3
Completion Status of Projects
The loans from the NABARD at concessional rates are
(RIDF-I to IV), as on 31 March 2002
given on the basis of state guarantees, to state governments,
and now local bodies and others. The centre announces the Area No. of No. of Per cent
NABARD’s corpus for this lending. The actual fund flow projects projects of projects
is from banks that were allowed to park funds with NABARD sanctioned completed completed
in lieu of their lending to the agriculture. Irrigation 85 40 47.1
Medium Irrigation 149 81 54.4
Bank Liberalization Minor Irrigation 17035 10996 64.5
Rural Roads 12660 9969 78.7
Simultaneously, the policy of priority sector lending to Rural Bridges 2546 2127 83.5
agriculture (and also to other sectors such as small-scale Watershed 192 102 53.1
industries) became problematic. The policy of directed Management
credit was not in tune with the liberalization of the banking Flood Protection 120 103 85.8
sector, but lacking good ideas on methods of ensuring Market Yard 18 0 0.0
Drainage 132 101 76.5
13 See chapter 6.1 by Tapas K. Sen in this report for a synoptic Others 17 13 76.5
view of the fiscal situation with regard to the states. Total 32954 23532 71.4
Rural Infrastructure 263

Table 9.4.4
Average Project size (Rs lakhs per project)

RIDF-I RIDF-II RIDF-III RIDF-IV RIDF-V RIDF-VI RIDF-VII


Irrigation 44.1 32.2 10.8 195.6 1.0 4.7 5.9
Rural roads 146.0 96.2 28.7 72.3 72.1 71.4 18.8
Rural bridges 17.8 22.9 29.9 29.9 15.1 33.6 32.5
Others 157.2 301.7 132.6 57.3 5.1 12.9 9.9

their targets to park funds with financial institutions like borrow from the RIDF since the rates were lower than what
the Small Industries Development Bank of India (SIDBI), they would have to pay in the market. NABARD took little
Housing and Urban Development Corporation (HUDCO) or no risks, and probably did not even really worry about
and NABARD which were deeply involved in their respective the project and its performance since the money was
priority areas. It would have been better to allow banks guaranteed by the state government by means of ‘irrevocable
to trade their priority sector portfolio so that the sector letters of authority (mandate) executed by the state
as a whole met the target14. This would have had the good governments and registered with the Reserve Bank of India
effect of converting a hard constraint to a soft one for (RBI) and Time Promissory Notes (TPNs) of the state
banks that had little motivation or competence to lend to governments’ (Annual Report, 2001–2, NABARD). But
agriculture and other priority sectors. Whereas those with lending to state governments did involve payments risk since
specialized competencies (including wider reach) in this many state governments have defaulted on salaries and even
direction could have built on their strengths by lending on pensions. That possibility was side-stepped at least on
even more than the stipulated limits15. But parking funds the books of NABARD through the above mentioned
with NABARD at least reduced the entry barriers for new guarantee, and by ensuring that lending growth (that is, of
banks, to usher in competition in the sector16. Nevertheless, outstanding) rates stayed higher than the rate of debt service.
given the macro-economic situation17, RIDF would have
been a godsend to public sector capital formation in ‘Ponzi Finance’?
agriculture. Projects of high return, essentially those that
In such a situation state governments could look forward
awaited funds for completion, (since they had been delayed
to cash inflows from new loans which would more than
inter alia due to capital scarcity post reform) were to be
cover the debt service. The day the rate of growth rate of
selected. The idea was not entirely motivated by the need
lending falls such that they do not deliver net resources to
to shift borrowings off the balance sheet. Guarantees of
the states, the incentive to default or delay payments can
state governments have, of course, gone up.
be high. Notice from the Table 9.4.1 that the disbursement
in the year 2000–1 was as much as Rs 3176 crore while
Guarantees of State Government
the repayments was Rs 866.15 crore. The current interest
The fiscal and transparency implications of the RIDF, though, rate is 10.5 per cent, and the repayment period is seven
are quirky. The state governments were quite willing to years with some rescheduling possible. This implies a service
14 For a discussion of how priority sector lending targets could
be incentivised, so that optimality in banks’ portfolios can emerge, Table 9.4.5
along with enhanced lending to the sectors, see Morris, (2001). Purpose-Wise Sanction of Loans under
15 Interest rate freedom does not exist for small loans. The regulated
All RIDF (31 March 2002)
low interest rates, could severely restrict fund flow to the sector.
16 Even that measure would not have arrested the relative decline
Purpose No. of (% to Amount (% to
of access to savings of the priority sectors. Being largely dependent on projects total) (Rs crore) total)
the banking sector, rather than on capital markets, as the disinvestment
process gathered momentum in the first half of the nineties, the flows Irrigation 165165 70.8 8332.66 35.6
on account of credit to the real sector fell quite rapidly. Rural Bridges 7593 3.3 3090.2 13.2
17 Credit was also affected by the sterilisation of capital inflows
Rural Roads 35954 15.4 9150.99 39.1
given money targeting. So agriculture even with RIDF and the Others* 24523 10.5 2858.64 12.2
continuance of priority sector lending could hope at best to hold to Total 233235 100.0 23432.49 100.0
a share of a cake whose size was rapidly shrinking. As gilt rates rose
with tight monetary targeting banks were comfortable parking funds Note: * Others include watershed development, flood protection,
in SLR securities. That would have aggravated the problem further market yard/godown, drainage, cold storage, fisheries, forest
for firms (small), and agriculture with comparative advantage for development, inland waterway, primary schools, public health,
accessing bank funds, and a disadvantage in going to capital markets. etc.
264 India Infrastructure Report 2003

rate of 21per cent of principal per annum. In other words, of two reasons. Irrigation has large social benefits in water-
if the nominal growth of disbursements is larger than this constrained and water-uncertain situations18. Since the
rate then the payments risk can be ‘side stepped’. From projects, especially those taken up in the first three rounds
Table 9.4.1 we see that the annual growth rate in of the RIDF, were those that had got delayed for inter alia
disbursements has been higher. The Compound Annual want of funds, the IRRs that are based on ignoring the
Growth Rates (CAGR) (1995–6 to 2001–2) is 39 per cent. sunk cost would naturally show very high returns. This is
Overall, credit expansion has been at a slower growth than as it should be since the RIDF was intended to be focused,
this at about 13.8 per cent (CAGR between 31 March 1996 to realize maximum social gain, by completing the projects.
and 31 March 2001), so banks may well be viewing NABARD Since the RIDF funds came on a route parallel to Plan
as parking for a return a shade better than on gilt. Funds, and with possibly less stringent ex-ante procedures
in spending, it was effective in completing long incomplete
NABARD’s Weak Incentive projects. Despite that, there were further delays of about
nearly three years in many cases.
Does the fact that the funds are being routed through a
financial intermediary with specialized skills in evaluation Better Management?
and monitoring and viability assessments make any
significant difference? On some key aspects of government Table 9.4.6 gives a sample of projects for which some
failure there is not much improvement. The studies (even information to work back to the overall time overrun was
the rather formal and possibly ritualized) variety carried available in the Annual Reports. Overall time overruns of
out by NABARD and its ‘consultants’ reveal that time the projects were very high and the RIDF was probably the
overruns were common. Project completion as per schedule key to their completion. Even if such projects represent
was rare, and delays of up to three years were common. those falling just around the one sigma value in terms of
The NABARD has little incentive to improve the situation. time overruns, the time overruns in irrigation projects in
First, independent of whether the projects were delayed general is likely to very high. This is in minor and medium
or completed, or even if they were quite uneconomical, irrigation projects that involve the state. One can well imagine
NABARD could look forward to debt and interest service. the situation with major irrigation projects.
All payments due were fully realized as is mentioned in The RIDF outlay as a proportion of total cost (including
the annual reports. State governments showed a tendency sunk cost) is small in the range of 15–18 per cent (see Table
to treat the disbursements under the RIDF as treasury 9.4.6). Thus, if RIDF could have ensured ‘that from now
transaction rather than being project related (though on on irrigation projects are going to be better managed’ then
paper they were). Therefore, little learning in lending to things could have really improved from the point of view
small infrastructure projects, and irrigation would have of the public exchequer. But there is no indication at all that
taken place. As such the perceived risk would continue to in any significant way, project management would have
remain high forever, condemning the set of activities to improved.
be risky in the eyes of financial intermediaries. We will
soon consider this aspect while discussing one CAG Report ‘Off Budget’ Borrowing
on Irrigation, which inter alia covered the RIDF. We could get just one independent reference to the RIDF.
That was by the CAG and pertained to the state of Rajasthan
High Social Returns and the RIDF was only a part of a comprehensive study
The Annual Reports of NABARD indicate very high of the working of the Irrigation Department. Rajasthan
financial rate of return on the irrigation projects. There could be considered as an average state on the aspect of
was no question of the rate of return in any commercial governance. Thus according to the Audit Report (Civil) for
sense being as high as the 30 per cent or more that many the year ended 31 March 2001 of the Irrigation Department:
projects seem to have. Irrigation benefits, though very
large, have hardly been appropriable in India, given the 18 The high returns to irrigation may be inferred from the high
virtual give away of public irrigation services. Typically, not marginal productivity of water, and the finding that irrigation supplies
even operational and maintenance costs tend to be recovered. best explain agricultural growth. Also in water-constrained areas,
That aspect has not changed at all. While part of the very the water market rates are high—far above the cost of public supply
high social rate of return on RIDF irrigation projects may with all its inefficiencies. The best indicator of the value of rural
bridges and road is the large price difference between farm gate and
not be borne by a more rigorous ex-post consideration of mandis, in many parts of rural India that are poorly connected. Also
the cost and benefits, the internal social rate of return are the mortality avoidable by being able to quickly access central
likely to be far above the cost of capital. This is because medical facilities is indicative.
Rural Infrastructure 265

Table 9.4.6
Benefits Derived from Select Irrigation Projects Financed Under RIDF

Project Time Capital RIDF Net RIDF FRR* Original Reference


overrun** cost Loan Increme- Outlay/ (%) starting year post
(%) (Rs cr) (Rs cr) ntal income Total date of the RIDF
(Rs per capital project
hectare) cost (%)
Tons Pump Canal 400 27.43 6.29 4061 18.7 29 1969 1998–9
(Allahabad, Uttar Pradesh)
Amipur Medium 375 10.93 1.45 9635 11.7 50+ 1978–9 1997–8
Irrigation Project
(Porbunder and
Junagadh, Gujarat)
Tilar Medium Irrigation 400 39.30 6.56 2932 14.3 46 1978 1998–9
Project (Sahajpur,
Madhya Pradesh)
Tank and Barrage Schemes N.A. 0.73 0.24 8896 24.7 48 N.A. 1997–8
(Vizag, Nalgonda and
Kurnool Andhra Pradesh)
Tank and Barrage Schemes 200 0.45 0.14 4720 23.7 42 1990 1998–9
(Chitradurga and Dharwad,
Karnataka)
Note: FRR—presumably ‘financial’ rate of return; N.A.—Not available
Source: From Table 4.6 of NABARD, Annual Report, 2000–1, and information in text. ‘Time overrun’ has been estimated using
a normal time of completion of four years for medium and three years for minor irrigation projects.

‘NABARD sanctioned 179 schemes under trench (sic.) check of 44 schemes sanctioned under RIDF-III revealed
I to VI of the RIDF of which 76 were completed (40 within that as against a loan of Rs 23.21 crore, Rs 40.96 crore
the targeted time and the rest after a delay of 1–3 years). and Rs 28.38 crore sanctioned for 1997–8,1998–9 and
Of the remaining 103 incomplete schemes, 50 were 1999–2000 respectively, the budget provision for these
scheduled to be completed by March 2001 and an projects/schemes were Rs 11.53 crore (50 per cent) Rs
expenditure of Rs 103.32 crore were incurred on these 24.54 crore (60 per cent) and 17.79 crore (63 per cent).
schemes. A test check of the completed projects revealed Eight schemes were completed within the stipulated time.
that canal work in respect of Boodpada (RIDF-I), Anandpur, Inadequate provision caused delay in completions of 36
Hamipur, Danpur, Bahadurpur, Bidloi (RIDF-II) and the schemes.’
head works in respect of Bhanpura (RIDF-II) were not ‘...The amount of loan Rs 1.16 crore drawn in excess of
complete but the schemes were declared complete’. expenditure on six completed and one dropped scheme by
(Emphasis Added.) the department was not utilized for the purpose for which
‘...An advance of Rs 9.45 crore for fifty-five schemes it was sanctioned.’
was received from NABARD during 1998–2000. The loan NABARD points to two aspects of the RIDF to make out
amount was credited to Internal Debt of the state government a case for success—the high social return and employment
from NABARD. None of these, except one, was started as generation and the near perfect repayment experience. We have
no budget was allotted by the FD [Finance Department] argued that these cannot be used as measures that are indicative
for these works and no advance was made available to the of the correctness of the design: the former is a matter of both
Irrigation Department. Instead Rs 9.10 crore (Rs 9.45– the high returns in irrigation per se and the fact that RIDF
0.35 crore) were not spent for the purpose it was sanctioned funds were instrumental in bringing about completion. The
but was used to boost ways and means position of the State. second is no measure either, given the guarantees and the fact
Further, interest liability of Rs 1.62 crore (up to March that governments have an incentive to repay when the
2001) was created.’ (Emphasis Added.) disbursement growth rates are higher than service rates.

Tardy Implementation Monitoring by NABARD


‘...The state government was required to make adequate The next question is, has NABARD’s involvement in any
budget provision for sanctioned schemes/projects. A test way improved the implementation of the projects? The
266 India Infrastructure Report 2003

Annual Report (2001–2) mentions ‘monitoring’ through Table 9.4.7


‘...desk reviews of periodic returns as also field visits... Results of a Regression: Log (Sanctions)
Services of consultants [Agricultural Finance Corporation]
Independent Coefficient t-value Sig.level
have also been commissioned for monitoring imple-
variable
mentation... Findings have been promptly communicated
to the [government]’. These efforts would have at best Constant ( ) –3.36608 –3.5840 0.0016
resulted in evaluatory assessments and not information for Log(Agri.Value 0.736696 10.1907 0.0000
corrections since they ignore time lag in the information, added) ( )
R-SQ. (ADJ.) 0.8108 No. of Obs 25
and the lead times for the government to act. These
analyses, mistakenly called monitoring, would have little Note: See text for explanations.
use in managerial actions to correct slippage and such
problems at the project level. At best they could inform
Time Overruns
the next round of implementation, or influence the strategy
of the next round, if there is learning taking place somewhere Based on the PCRs sent by the state governments, NABARD
in government. But this is doubtful because there are consolidated the PCRs for the projects of the first tranche
hardly any organizational processes or structure, that allow to report: ‘The time lag between allocation of funds, actual
embedding of learning in government. sanction and the first disbursement ranged from six months
to more than a year. Time overrun has been very common
Chief Secretary to Monitor? in the irrigation projects. All the projects sanctioned under
RIDF-I were to be completed by March 1997. However,
More importantly ‘.. the progress in the implementation
by that date only 543 projects (13 per cent of total) would
of projects continued to be reviewed in quarterly meetings
be completed. .......The delayed completion/implementation
of the High Power Committee (HPC) constituted for the
of projects was due to faulty formulation of projects,
purpose in each of the states under the chairmanship of
inadequacies in appraisal and sanction and poor monitoring
the Chief Secretary/Finance Secretary of the state’ (Annual
Report, NABARD, 2000–1). It is a moot point if the of progress of implementation. The cost overrun as compared
roughly 10,000 projects per state can in any way be to original estimates was on an average 7.79 per cent over
meaningfully reviewed except on macro (economic) the period...’ If this assessment is to be relied upon (recall
aggregative and overall financial dimensions, by chief the comments of the CAG on the situation with regard to
secretaries who have many other pressing matters. Thus, the RIDF in Rajasthan earlier), then clearly the time delays
if land acquisition is found to be a major cause for delay are significant. A rough assessment of the time delays in
what can the HPC do? There is no way the specifics of relation to the completion times stipulated at approval that
a project could be brought out at so high a level, but the this 13 per cent completion would mean is about 60 per
specifics are necessary for corrective action. It falls into cent! This is of course for the ‘to be completed’ part of the
the same trap, rife in government systems and thinking project. Thus, when there are delays of this magnitude for
in India, that information alone can lead to correct action, the work taken up specifically for speedy completion then
even if incentives are unaligned or perversely aligned against for irrigation projects as such in all probability there would
the performance of the primary task. Only common general have been little or no change for the better. Reported cost
problems could at best emerge (assuming that the reporting overruns are small. Here the data could be relied upon. The
systems correctly gather the information and tabulate the delayed decisions affect the physical start of project
same). But the general problems are known and their implementation and the completion time once the work has
resolution involves deeper changes in the politics, started. Much of the delays are in the pre-physical
macroeconomics, the law and the working of the implementation stage, and the costs incurred (or benefits
bureaucracy19. So we cannot but conclude that the RIDF lost) during this period would not have been taken into
too fits in with the ritualization of evaluation and monitoring account, since the usage of the fund as such starts ticking
that is widespread in government today. The only thing only with the first disbursements. So delays pre-disbursement
positive here is that since funding is from an external body, would not add to cost for the NABARD outlay, though
the form of reporting, monitoring and assessment would delays post disbursement would. So the cost overrun figures
be adhered to better. have limited meaning since they do not take into account
the benefits lost on delayed completion. Even then there
19 Refer to Chapter 5.1, by Sebastian Morris in this report for is a certain improvement in that the money being routed
the general factors causing time overruns in public sector peojects, through a financial institution (independent of the state
at the central level. The next paragraph brings out the general factors government) would mean that at least all the known ex ante
in time overrun of RIDF irrigation projects. difficulties would have influenced the disbursal of funds.
Rural Infrastructure 267

Table 9.4.8
Ratio of Observed ‘Sanctions to Predicted Sanction’, and Observed to ‘Predicted Disbursals’

State Sanctions under Agricultural Ratio of observed Disbursals Ratio of disbur-


all RIDF cumulative value added at to ‘Predicted’ (Rs cr) sals to ‘predicted
(Rs cr) current prices, sanctions disbursals’
c. 1997–8
Manipur 10.08 46989 0.11 0.96 1.03
Bihara 432.71 1334617 0.39 42.04 0.22
Assam 389.79 658691 0.58 225.02 1.31
Haryana 613.44 1216376 0.58 300.68 1.03
Punjab 907.49 1759870 0.66 578.50 1.26
Sikkim 40.04 23104 0.71 31.45 2.60
Goa 50.66 26965 0.80 27.13 1.70
Rajasthan 1352.13 2064891 0.87 842.35 1.15
Tripura 108.9 61151 0.94 20.21 0.52
Kerala 843.63 950326 0.96 432.26 1.02
Uttar Pradesh 2741.21 4386323 1.02 1613.46 0.97
West Bengal 1757.26 2274283 1.06 886.57 0.89
Karnataka 1531.86 1720204 1.13 802.65 0.95
Gujarat 1431.36 1530338 1.15 878.90 1.13
Maharashtra 2293.94 2901190 1.15 1397.04 0.88
Meghalaya 103.67 42529 1.17 47.15 0.40
Madhya Pradesh 1948.18 2148754 1.22 985.59 1.65
Mizoram 67.64 19989 1.33 36.81 1.29
Tamil Nadu 1507.55 1262639 1.40 941.57 1.14
Nagaland 81.06 22400 1.47 28.02 1.02
Orissa 1020.33 638032 1.56 608.78 1.16
Andhra Pradesh 2741.41 2417704 1.57 1591.89 0.96
Jammu & Kashmir 645.22 211107 2.23 291.17 0.94
Arunachal Pradesh 183.01 32733 2.50 68.55 0.96
Himachal Pradesh 630.91 146838 2.85 362.37 1.21
Notes: a The ‘sanctions’ predicted are from a model that estimates the sanctions as a function of agricultural GDP c. 1997–8 of the
states; and ‘predicted’ disbursements from a model that estimates disbursements as a linear function of sanctions. See text for details.
Including Jharkhand, Uttaranchal and Chattisgarh, respectively.

Better Allocative Efficiency category states are left out, then Bihar with little or no
That takes us to the state-wise distribution of RIDF. discipline to even submit project proposals, and others
Interestingly, it is here where we see some difference in under severe fiscal stress, for example, Assam, Kerala,
outcomes over routing the same funds through the usual Punjab and Haryana (and also because they have much
ministerial and planning commission channels. Annexure infrastructure already in place) and, possibly, Uttar Pradesh
4.1 of the NABARD Annual Report 2001–2 gives the show poorer sanctions. Similarly, in the next stage estimating
state-wise sanctions and disbursals of the various tranches. disbursals conditional on sanctions we find that disbursals
The aggregate over the tranches of sanctions and disbursals have been poor for Bihar and Tripura and not particularly
have been taken and a simple model fitted to ‘explain’ different for the others. Thus, except for Bihar, the NABARD
sanctions as a function of the agricultural value added of sanctions, more than disbursals (conditional on sanctions),
the state (taking 1996–7 figures). bring out the evidence that NABARD does recognize and
The Model: log(Sanctions)= a + b*log(Agricultural value use state failure and the fiscal situation in its sanctions and
added); was estimated with a high degree of fit (see Table disbursals, but perhaps very weakly. But even this is a
9.4.7 for the results), and the ratio of the observed sanctions significant improvement over direct allocations by the
to the ‘predicted’ sanction is reported in Table 9.4.8. central government. This perhaps is the major gain in the
Observe that there is significant variation. If the special RIDF mechanism.
268 India Infrastructure Report 2003

REFERENCES

——— (1980), ‘Social Benefit Cost Analysis of the Rengali Mundle, Sudipto and M. Govinda Rao (1991), ‘The Volume
Multi-Purpose Project, Orissa’, mimeo, Kanpur: Indian and Composition of Subsidies in India 1987–9’, Economic
Institute of Technology. and Political Weekly, Mumbai.
———(1976), ‘Performance of Irrigation Projects’, Economic NABARD, Annual Reports, 2001–2, 1999–2000 and 1998–9.
and Political Weekly, Vol. 11 No. 3. NIRD (2000), Background papers prepared for the National
———(1992), ‘World Development Report, 1992’, New York: Workshop on Follow-up Measures by State Governments on
Oxford University Press. SFC Recommendations, organized by the State Finance
Aziz, Abdul (1998), Income Structure of Rural Local Governments: Commission Cell, National Institute of Rural Development,
The Karnataka Experience, Local Government Finances in Hyderabad, 3–4 October 2002.
India, Konard Adenauer Foundation, New Delhi: Manohar. Oommen, J. (1998), Panchayati Raj Finances in Kerala: Tasks
Bardhan, Pranab (2000). ‘Irrigation and Co-operation: An Empirical Ahead, Local Government Finances in India, Konard
Analysis of 48 Irrigation Communities in South Asia’, Adenauer Foundation, New Delhi: Manohar.
Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 48 No. 4 Oommen, M.A. (1998), Devolution of Resources to Rural Local
pp. 847–65. Bodies: A Comparative Study of Select State Finance
CFC (2000), Report of the Eleventh Finance Commission for 2000– Commission Reports, ISS Occasional Paper Series 21, New
2005, Special Supplement No.3 of 2000 to (m), Book info, Delhi: Institute of Social Sciences.
a monthly Information Relating to New Available law and Pal, S. (1985), ‘Contribution of Irrigation to Agricultural
other publications plus news from government gazettes, Production and Productivity’, New Delhi: National Council
etc., New Delhi: Akalanle Publications. of Applied Economic Research.
Dhawan, B.D. (1988), ‘Irrigation in India’s Development, Rath, Binayak (1993), ‘Management of Irrigation Projects in
Productivity, Stability, Equity’, New Delhi: Sage Publications. India’, mimeo, Kanpur: Indian Institute of Technology.
Government of India (1992), ‘Report of the Committee on Reports of First Finance Commissions of various states including
pricing of Irrigation Water’, New Delhi: Planning Kerala, Punjab and West Bengal.
Commission.
Rogers, P. (1983), ‘Irrigation and Economic Development: Some
Government of India (1972), ‘Report of Irrigation Commission
Lessons from India’, Harvard: Cambridge University.
(RIC)’, New Delhi: Ministry of Irrigation and Power.
Shah, Amita (1998), ‘Water Development Programmes in India:
Government of India (1998), ‘Water Related Statistics’, New
Emerging Issues for Environment Development Perspectives’,
Delhi: Central Water Commission.
Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 33 No. 26, pp. A 66–79.
Mathew, G. (2000), Status of Panchayati Raj in India, New
Srivastava D.K. and Tapas K. Sen (1997), ‘Government Subsidies
Delhi: Institute of Social Sciences.
in India’, New Delhi: National Institute of Public Finance
Mathur, M.P. (1999), The Constitution (74th) Amendment Act and
and Policy.
Urban Local Governments: An Overview, Urban India, A Journal
of the National Institute of Urban Affairs, Vol. XIX, No.1, Vaidyanathan A., Asha Krishnakumar, A. Rajagopal and D.
January–June. Varatharajan (1994), ‘Impact of Irrigation on Productivity
Mathur, O.P. (2000), Decentralization in India: A Report Card, of Lnad’, Journal of Indian School of Political Economy, Oct–
UMP-ASIA Occasional Paper No. 47, UNDP/ Dec.
UNCHS(Habitat)/World Bank Urban Management Verghese, B.G.(1990), Water of Hope: Integrated Water Resource
Programme, Regional Office for Asia and the Pacific, Asian Development and Regional Cooperation within the Himalayan
Institute of Technology (AIT), Bangkok, Thailand. Ganga– Brahamputra Barak Basin, New Delhi: Oxford
Meench, Marcus (1998), ‘Allocating the Common Heritage: IBH Publishing Co.
Debates over Water Rights and Governance Structure in Verma, Neelamani P. (1987), ‘Impact of Irrigation on Agricultural
India’, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 33 No. 26, pp. Structure and Productivity: A Case Study of Uttar Pradesh
A46–53. in a Spatial Framework’, mimeo, Faizabad: Avadh University.
Morris, S. (2001), ‘Finance and Small Firms,’ in Morris et al. Wade, R. (1982), ‘The World Bank and India’s Irrigation
Morris, S., Rakesh Basant, K. Das, K. Ramachandran, and A. Reforms’, Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 18 No.2.
Koshy (2001), Growth and Transformation of Small Firms World Bank (1993), ‘Water Resources Management, A World
in India, New Delhi: Oxford University Press. Bank Policy Paper’, Washington D.C.: World Bank.

You might also like