Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 10

Journal of Cleaner Production 15 (2007) 557e566

www.elsevier.com/locate/jclepro

Making consumption ‘‘reasonable’’


Jakub Kronenberg
Department of International Economics, University of Lodz, POW 3/5, 90-255 Lodz, Poland
Accepted 25 May 2006
Available online 5 September 2006

Abstract

In light of the theoretical implications from ecological economics and industrial ecology, increased efforts should be undertaken by policy
makers to make consumption ‘‘reasonable’’. To remain sustainable, ‘‘reasonable’’ decisions should take into account the long-term survival of
ecosystem and acknowledge the fact that the existence of human species ultimately depends on it. Two additional objectives should complement
‘‘reasonable’’ consumption: (1) changing product systems so that products are properly managed at the end of their useful lives. (2) making
products more environmentally friendly. A case study of the Integrated Product Policy of the European Union reveals that it addresses the above
objectives selectively. The general conclusions are that ‘‘reasonable’’ behaviour is challenged by conflicting interests of various market actors,
that economic reasoning should complement environmentally ‘‘reasonable’’ behaviour, and that ‘‘reasonable’’ consumption should indeed be
discussed in conjunction with ‘‘reasonable’’ production.
Ó 2006 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Sustainable consumption; Sustainable production; Industrial ecology; Ecological economics; Integrated Product Policy

1. Introduction thus forces a more detailed description of what we intend to


achieve calling for ‘‘sustainable’’ consumption (discussed in
In this article, I combine the notion of ‘‘reasonable’’ and Section 2 of this article). Secondly, agreeing that such a de-
‘‘sustainable’’, and I argue that making consumption scription is ‘‘reasonable’’, stakeholders may find denying it
‘‘reasonable’’ should also make it sustainable. In this sense, more difficult, than they find denying, else abusing, the notion
‘‘reasonable’’ means interested in the long-term survival of of ‘‘sustainability’’. Thus, although the conceptual analysis
ecosystem and acknowledging the fact that the existence of performed in this article is based on a wordplay, it brings about
human species ultimately depends on it. In practice, this new insights into the epistemological foundations of consumer
relates to the need to make consumers aware of the link decisions. Also, it indicates that using a similar ‘‘trick’’ can
between their consumption patterns and the environmental enhance the influence that the proponents of ‘‘sustainability’’
problems that they hear about in the news. have had so far.
The notion of ‘‘reasonable’’ consumption conforms with The ideas put forward in this article originate from a detailed
the extant body of literature on sustainable consumption, ques- study of the theoretical foundations of ecological economics and
tioning the association between consumption (material industrial ecology and their policy implications [6]. Following
consumption in particular) and welfare (e.g. [1e5]). A seem- an interdisciplinary and integrated approach, ecological eco-
ingly obvious claim that reason should be employed more nomics and industrial ecology provide the most comprehensive
often to guide consumer behaviour, puts the current debate framework for studying economyeenvironment interactions.
on sustainable consumption and production in a new light. For this reason, they tend to be called the ‘‘science of sustain-
Firstly, it requires a definition of what is ‘‘reasonable’’ and ability’’ which guarantees that grounding the concept of
‘‘reasonable’’ consumption in the analysis of their theoretical
implications is in line with the principle of sustainable develop-
E-mail address: j.kronenberg@gmail.com ment. Ecological economics and industrial ecology share three

0959-6526/$ - see front matter Ó 2006 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2006.05.012
558 J. Kronenberg / Journal of Cleaner Production 15 (2007) 557e566

levels of considerations, an overview of which is presented in 1. making consumption ‘‘reasonable’’ (discussed in Section 3),
Table 1. To these, industrial ecologists add the metaphor com- primarily through:
paring industrial systems to ecosystems, emphasising the need a. reducing material consumption (Subsection 3.1);
to imitate natural resilience, efficiency, interconnectedness b. shifting to consuming function rather than matter
and sufficiency in industry. Furthermore, both ecological econ- (Subsection 3.2);
omists and industrial ecologists acknowledge the fact that 2. changing product systems so that products are properly
‘‘goods which are ‘consumed’ really only render certain ser- managed at the end of their useful lives (Subsection 4.1); and
vices’’ [7], thus supporting the idea of functionality. 3. incremental product improvement (making products more
The theoretical implications from ecological economics and environmentally friendly; Subsection 4.2).
industrial ecology can be translated into the following
objectives for a sustainable consumption and production The above objectives are in line with the strategies to deal
policy: with sustainable consumption and production put forward by

Table 1
Three levels of considerations shared by ecological economics and industrial ecology and their implications for sustainable consumption and production
Consideration level Consideration Implication
Primary Economic and natural The same biophysical laws that govern nature also govern the economy
(biophysical) systems coevolve Neither products nor the economic processes related to them can be analysed without
reference to ecosystems
Product life-cycles should not be perceived as linear but as cyclic, just as
life-cycles in nature
The Earth’s carrying Need to establish the ecological limits of unsustainable scale and to establish policies that
capacity has to be obeyed assure that the throughput of the economy stays within these limits [8]
Relative eco-efficiency is not enough
The goal is to decouple economic growth from its environmental impacts
‘‘Policies matter’’
Addressing key areas of concern is more relevant than referring to the overall indicators
Resources and energy It takes time to reproduce resources so they should be used efficiently
are not created ex nihilo Natural (traditional) products that involve less processing should be preferred
Man-made capital cannot Man-made capital and natural capital are complementary
substitute for natural capital
‘‘All production is joint The production of wanted goods always gives rise to additional unwanted
production’’ [9] outputs, which may be harmful to the environment
Need to adopt an integrated approach to processes and products to minimise waste
Need to introduce changes in the composition of desired products or their absolute amounts
Need of careful studies of outputs (some by-products do not appear on the market)
Providing consumers with information about the undesired joint products
of products they consume
Resources and energy cannot At some point the amount of exergy required for recycling outweighs the amount of energy
be completely recycled embodied in the recycled output
‘‘Closing the loop’’ e support reuse, recycling and recovery of materials, wherever it is
environmentally and economically viable

Secondary Intertemporal analysis Emphasis on intergenerational equity; attention paid to long-term future issues;
(economic) invoking an historical perspective
Institutional analysis of Transaction, empowerment and government failures [10]
failures Need for a fair and just distribution of resources using systems of property
rights and transfers [8]
Market failures Need for direct intervention aiming at correcting the distorted market prices e
‘‘getting the prices right’’
Internalisation Producers and users should pay for the damage they cause; supporting market based
mechanisms to allocate resources efficiently, such as the ecological fiscal reform

Tertiary Systems perspective ‘‘Everything is connected’’


(strategic) Epistemological analysis Our understanding of the economyeenvironment interactions is limited; future is open and
unknowable; apart from risk and uncertainty our analyses are also bounded by ignorance
(see ref [11])
Precautionary principle Need for precautionary principle, principally due to our ignorance
Pollution/waste prevention Preventing pollution and waste from happening as a first-best strategy
J. Kronenberg / Journal of Cleaner Production 15 (2007) 557e566 559

other authors, in particular Oosterhuis et al. [12] and Reisch The approach we adopt even before we start an analysis
[13]; see Table 2. To some extent, the first objective encom- clearly influences our future understanding of any issue. These
passes the latter two. However, for the sake of clarity, I have approaches can be referred to as paradigms (in the sense of
decided to differentiate between them on the basis that the Kuhn), preanalytic visions (Schumpeter’s terminology) or
latter two focus on instruments targeted at producers, while mental models (systems thinking). In the ecological econom-
the first one targets both producers and consumers. Taken ics and industrial ecology debate, the fundamental paradigm
together, these objectives are meant to contribute to says that the economy is just a subsystem of a larger natural
sustainable development and should be addressed in this hier- system and, thus, that both systems mutually influence each
archically descending order. In Section 5, I test whether they other. So far, this has not been acknowledged in most policies
are used in the practice of sustainable production and con- aimed at consumption and production. Changing this mental
sumption policies, using the example of the Integrated Product model, like changing most of the mental models we use,
Policy of the European Union. constitutes a leverage point, through which we can achieve
disproportionately high results [14]. Once this is acknowl-
2. Rationale for ‘‘reasonable’’ consumption edged, further implications from ecological economics and
industrial ecology become more obvious, such as the fact
Problems with unsustainable production and consumption that the same biophysical laws that govern nature also govern
result from paradigms on which our socio-economic systems the economy. Moreover, it becomes clear that the scale of
are based, from insufficient knowledge about economye economic activity is bounded by the Earth’s carrying capacity
environment interactions and from information asymmetries. and, consequently, that attempts should be made to limit the
These lead to major problems, such as overseeing the environ- throughput of economic systems.
mental impacts of aggregate consumption levels and indirect In spite of many attempts to analyse the interactions
environmental impacts of products. The idea of reasonable between the economy and the environment (so far undertaken
consumption responds to these challenges. Employing reason fa- mostly within ecological economics and industrial ecology),
cilitates paradigm shifts and, in particular, helps to reduce infor- these are still full of unknowns and we keep being surprised
mation deficits. Indeed, ‘‘reasonable’’ consumption liberates us by some of them. Obviously, we now know more than we
from the mainstream thinking regarding economyeenvironment used to know 30 years ago, but still we do not know enough
interactions. While ‘‘sustainable’’ has become a cliché, already to make accurate predictions regarding the overall impacts
repeated so many times without much impact, ‘‘reasonable’’ that the economy might have on the environment. Thus,
requires the use of reason and questions mainstream paradigms. ‘‘the acceptance of our ignorance is a first step in creating
Current unsustainable consumption patterns result to a large a more rational approach to environmental policy’’ [15]. If
extent from the fact that preferences expressed in the market we do not know something, the reasonable approach is to
do not necessarily reflect the real perceptions of consumers, take precautions. Otherwise, we run an incalculable risk of
as they are affected by inadequate knowledge. Information committing a mistake, which, furthermore, might have crucial
deficits result from the fact that most of the current knowledge consequences for the existence and stability of our system.
does not even consider the links between the economy and the Both of the above problems lead to insufficient information
environment. Even when it does, our knowledge regarding on the environmental impacts of consumption, which is further
these interactions is limited and full of unknowns. exacerbated by the information asymmetries between

Table 2
Objectives for a sustainable consumption policy put forward in this article compared to other suggestions (with original hierarchy in brackets)
Objectives suggested in this article Objectives suggested by Objectives suggested by Reisch [13]
Oosterhuis et al. [12]
Making consumption Reducing material consumption Lowering the product throughput Motivate consumers to make more
‘‘reasonable’’ (reducing the overall materials sustainable decisions (2)
Shifting to consuming function throughput of the economic Lay foundations for a structural change
rather than matter processes and reducing the overall towards sufficiency-based behaviour (3)
amount of products used) (1)
Changing product systems Changing the product use and disposal Design market conditions e institutions,
so that products are properly in an environmentally sound direction instruments and infrastructure e ‘‘so that
managed at the end of their (shaping the way in which a product is demand not only supports consumer
useful lives used and disposed of, e.g. reuse and interests but also all those of the economy
recycling) (3) and society’’ (1)
Incremental product improvement Changing the product with regard to its
(making products more environmentally harmful features
environmentally friendly (all kinds of changes in the product,
such as reduction and substitution of
environmentally harmful substances) (2)
560 J. Kronenberg / Journal of Cleaner Production 15 (2007) 557e566

consumers and producers. Placing more emphasis on informa- patterns are far from sustainable. Instead, I combine the notion
tion and communication can help to change paradigms, to re- of ‘‘reasonable’’ and ‘‘sustainable’’, and I argue that making
duce the information failure, and to alleviate information consumption ‘‘reasonable’’ should also make it sustainable.
asymmetries between producers and consumers. To know
what is needed to assure ecosystem and human survival, we 3. Making consumption reasonable
have to refer to ecological economics and the collateral field
of industrial ecology, both of which provide the most compre- Based on the tenets outlined in the previous section, scien-
hensive framework available to study economyeenvironment tists are increasingly aware of the complexity of the world
interactions. that surrounds us and, in response, seek to undertake interdis-
Taking into consideration the above problems, two issues ciplinary research efforts. Future research into consumption
related to consumption seem not to have been given enough problems is likely to combine the social science approach
attention in the sustainable consumption and production debate: focusing on incremental environmental improvement and the
biophysical perspective pointing at problems such as scale or
- aggregate consumption levels; and irreversibility [17]. Once environmental problems gain even
- indirect environmental effects associated with products. more attention from the public, information acquired through
such research will become increasingly demanded by govern-
Perceiving the economy as part of a larger ecosystem makes ments and other decision makers. The notion of reasonable
it clear that there are limits to aggregate consumption. Mean- consumption refers to making informed choices in the market.
while, efficiency gains in production often provoke consump- Ultimately, consumers themselves, given appropriate informa-
tion growth which has been termed as the rebound effect. tion and education, should be able to assess their consumption
Thus, in industry, just as in nature, efficiency of production patterns and mitigate them accordingly.
has to be complemented with ‘‘sufficiency’’ in consumption. Communication and information sharing constitute essential
It is also in line with the widely declared approach of avoiding issues in industrial ecology, as they enhance interconnectedness
problems at source, rather than mitigating their negative results. within the system and facilitate all interdisciplinary undertak-
Furthermore, indirect impacts that products exert on hu- ings and, ultimately, the system’s sustainability. A policy aimed
man societies and the environment frequently outweigh those at sustainable consumption and production should support the
directly associated with the product’s life-cycle. For instance, exchange of information among companies, between compa-
a car constitutes an example of a single product to which our nies and consumers, between companies and governments
culture and societies have now almost completely adjusted. and among the various government agencies involved. Policy
Therefore, the most significant impacts that cars exert on instruments should shape consumer behaviour by influencing
the environment are not related to cars themselves (their pro- their beliefs, attitudes and expectations related to eco-designed
duction, use and disposal) or their subsystems (heating, en- products. This should lead to changing the consumers’ percep-
gine etc.), but to the system changes they have brought tion of values, needs and the means of their satisfaction.
about in infrastructure and culture. This clearly indicates Information flows constitute an important leverage point for
a need for a systems approach to studying the impacts of changing consumption patterns [14]. The sustainability of con-
complex and socially influential products, such as passenger sumption depends, to a large extent, on information about the
cars. possibility of ‘‘making a difference’’ and how to make it, as
Thus, enhancing information flows, communication and well as on the attitudes of other relevant actors (and their
education, can have potentially significant influence on the potential assistance to consumer decision making) [18]. Nev-
sustainability of consumption. If a holistic systems approach ertheless, consumers are not able to deal with excessive
is applied to studying economyeenvironment interactions amounts of information and intermediaries are necessary to
and if more emphasis is placed on educating consumers about pass the information from companies to consumers. Consumer
the influence that consumption has on the environment, and business education, complemented with the stimulation
consumption may become more ‘‘reasonable’’. In this sense, and facilitation of environmentally friendly patterns of behav-
‘‘reasonable’’ means interested in the long-term survival of iour, emerges as an appropriate solution.
the ecosystem and acknowledging the fact that the existence In short, the concept of ‘‘reasonable’’ consumption is based
of the human species ultimately depends on it. It eventually on the assumption that if consumers are provided with reliable
takes into consideration the long-term interests of the whole and comprehensive information about the environmental con-
system within which consumers operate. Thus, it is distant sequences of their choices, they will be likely to change them
from the narrow, microeconomic understanding of reasonable in a more sustainable direction. However, such informative
consumer decisions as driven by two-dimensional preferences, incentives should be complemented with economic measures
considering only direct costs and outcomes. It is also distant directed also at appealing to the consumers’ economic reason-
from Weber’s notion of rationalisation, as applied to consump- ing. Two most important changes in consumption patterns,
tion by Ritzer [16], which ultimately leads to narrowing the crucial in the light of ecological economics and industrial
choices available to consumers in an attempt to make their ecology, include reducing material consumption and shifting
decisions as easy and efficient as possible. As the latter two to consuming function rather than matter, as argued in the
understandings of reasonability dominate, consumption following two subsections.
J. Kronenberg / Journal of Cleaner Production 15 (2007) 557e566 561

3.1. Reducing material consumption but it would require changes in their mental models. Among
the most important of those is the realisation that products
In an attempt to make consumption ‘‘reasonable’’, it appears only provide certain services and that what is consumed is
necessary to reduce material consumption. Ecological econom- their function (or utility) and not their physical properties.
ics and industrial ecology clearly indicate the need to limit the
individual consumption of products and thus reduce economic 3.2. Shifting to consuming function rather than matter
throughput. Reducing material consumption should help to
achieve the decoupling of economic growth from resource con- Reducing material consumption does not lead to a decrease
sumption and pollution generation. in well-being, as long as matter is replaced by non-material
Although sustainable consumption has been widely consumption. A sustainable consumption and production
discussed since 1992, consumption levels have continued to policy should support the economy based on functionality.
increase. Among the most obvious examples of areas where The issue of reducing consumption is closely related to seek-
material consumption has become particularly exuberant, ing alternative ways to satisfy needs, sometimes also referred
and which, at the same time, can be relatively easily pre- to as ‘‘servicisation’’ e shifting towards a service-based econ-
vented, is that of disposable products. With cultural changes omy. However, ‘‘servicisation’’ may also reflect the rising
preferring convenience life-styles, and with lower production share of services in the GDP, that may appear in parallel to
costs gained through economies of scale, an increasing range an increasing material production and consumption. There-
of products have acquired disposable substitutes. Meanwhile, fore, the economy based on functionality constitutes a more
‘‘reasonable’’ consumption remains on a par with real needs. appropriate objective, as it refers to putting the emphasis on
Although humans are not machines and their decisions are obtaining the function that a product or service delivers instead
influenced by factors other than pure reason (emotions, of a product in its material form.
symbolism, participation in society etc.), ‘‘reasonable’’ con- Following the arguments of Max-Neef [1,2], Mont [5] reiter-
sumption indicates a direction in which consumption would ated that consumer needs can be satisfied by non-material satis-
have to evolve to become sustainable. fiers as well as by material products. Max-Neef’s ‘‘threshold
As consumers are not likely to change their consumption hypothesis’’ suggested that economic growth (and material con-
habits in response to information about their environmental sumption in particular) can only increase human welfare to a cer-
impacts only, their choices can be aided by a government tain level, beyond which they often diverge. This links to the
policy. Obviously, reducing consumption should not be microeconomic notion of diminishing marginal utility of con-
performed in the form of production or consumption bans sumption. Mont [5] also raised further issues contradicting the
(with certain exceptions, just as governments are entitled to positive correlation between material consumption and well-
ban, or at least make illegal, the consumption of drugs). being. Their list can be extended, for example with negative health
Rather, economic instruments should be sought that can effec- effects often associated with excessive material consumption.
tively contribute to lowering consumption through increasing It will be the policy makers’ task to provide incentives for
prices, especially of products that are judged particularly producers, so that they provide further incentives to con-
harmful to the environment. As major environmental impacts sumers. Involving industry is crucial for the success of this
of many products arise during the use phase, users should be objective. Once business is convinced, it will take over and,
made responsible for the damage they cause. as it is very keen on selling goods and services, it should be
Educational and informative activities should be carried out very effective in so doing. Meanwhile, the idea of selling ser-
on the reasons for undertaking such a policy, on its benefits for vices instead of products has first to be sold to business which,
consumers and on the alternative means of satisfying con- should be carried out principally with the use of economic
sumption needs. Consumers should also be educated on health instruments, such as those altering the prices of resources.
issues related to excessive consumption, especially those Both reducing material consumption and shifting to con-
following the adoption of the convenience life-style (such as suming function rather than matter contribute to more
convenience foods). Finally, indicators such as GDP, or the ‘‘reasonable’’ consumption. However, a policy also has to
number of cars per 1000 inhabitants, should no longer be take into consideration that not all material consumption can
used to describe well-being. They ultimately have to be be avoided or replaced by services. In those cases, focus
replaced by indicators representing sustainability, addressing should be placed on the complementary objectives of proper
the issue of the scale of the economy in relation to the environ- end-of-life management of products and their incremental im-
ment. Inputeoutput analysis and industrial metabolism provement through eco-design, discussed in the next section.
methods (such as material flow accounting or substance flow Furthermore, production can be made more sustainable in at
analysis) should be used to complement any statistical infor- least two other ways. Firstly, appealing to producers’ eco-
mation referring to well-being. After all, any sustainable nomic rationalisation, internalisation of externalities has to
consumption and production policy ultimately refers to man- be made beneficial through economic incentives or disincen-
aging material flows within the economy. tives introduced by policy makers. Secondly, environmentally
In summary, reducing material consumption emerges as an ‘‘reasonable’’ behaviour of companies can be influenced by
elementary implication for sustainable consumption. It would ‘‘reasonable’’ consumption e the pressure from consumers
not translate into lowering the well-being of modern societies, wanting to behave in a environmentally ‘‘reasonable’’ way.
562 J. Kronenberg / Journal of Cleaner Production 15 (2007) 557e566

This further confirms the need to make consumption ‘‘reason- (durable and functional) products satisfy consumer needs
able’’, meaning guided by reason rather than emotions. more efficiently and, thus, less of them are necessary. With
regard to product improvement, LCA and eco-design are the
4. Complementary objectives most important strategies. They should be as participatory as
possible, thus enhancing mutual trust between producers, con-
4.1. Organising end-of-life management of products sumers, society and policy makers. Again, information and
communication about the products’ characteristics have to
‘‘Reasonable’’ consumption constitutes the first-best objec- constitute important elements of this objective (thus, appealing
tive. In the case of products the consumption of which cannot to consumers’ reason).
be avoided or substituted with services, proper take-back and To facilitate take-back and appropriate end-of-life manage-
end-of-life management should be ensured. Indeed, if taken ment, products should be designed in an appropriate way.
back and managed properly, it can be argued that products Often, changing the properties of a product (e.g. increasing
have fulfilled their function, and the resources of which they its durability), even though it may stimulate new demand,
have been composed can be used for a different purpose. Here, will not necessarily contribute to increasing the throughput.
I refer to strategies directed at preventing waste from being dis- Rather, when combined with proper use that can also be
persed in the environment and, thus, from becoming pollution. shaped by relevant policy instruments, it will lead to more
The main advantage of reuse, remanufacturing, recycling ‘‘reasonable’’ and thus sustainable consumption.
and even the incineration of products with energy recovery Better quality products, although their unit price is higher,
is that they prevent waste from becoming pollution, as they often prove to be cheaper because of their longevity and better
provide a use for it. If, following the logic of industrial eco- performance (batteries provide a good example). Educating
logy, one assumes that wastes can be reused, reducing consumers about the advantages of using better quality prod-
consumption becomes less necessary, as long as consumption ucts, that are more expensive but of which the performance
can be based on the continuous use of resources quasi- and durability are higher, should also be addressed in sustain-
constantly circulating within the economy. Nevertheless, these able consumption and production policies.
strategies only appear as a second-best solution, as they Thus, governments also need to influence producers so that
destroy the functionality embedded in products. Moreover, they change what is available to consume e principally in
recycling is not always environmentally and economically terms of providing consumers with alternative consumption
viable and is affected by the problem of ‘‘downcycling’’, as options, but also in terms of marketing eco-designed products.
continuously recycled materials gradually loose their func-
tional features. The problem of environmental and economic 5. A case study of the IPP
viability also affects other strategies for the end-of-life man-
agement of products. As a case study, I discuss whether the Integrated Product
The efficient use of resources (which can be achieved Policy of the European Union satisfies the objectives sug-
through various types of product standards) is another strategy gested in the preceding sections.
advocated on the basis of ecological economics. Furthermore, In the European Union, a new policy framework emerges to
the industrial ecological metaphor particularly strongly promote sustainable consumption and production e the Inte-
emphasises the issue of closing material cycles (hence the grated Product Policy (IPP). The IPP will primarily focus on
organisation of product take-back schemes, minimum recycled the life-cycle approach as an innovative foundation for policy
content standards etc.). Extended producer responsibility and making. This further requires adopting an integrated and
sustainable product chain management are among the most interdisciplinary approach (thus also cooperation and commu-
important strategies to satisfy this objective. They allow for nication within product chains) and fostering innovation. Alto-
arranging the proper end-of-life management of products. As gether, these will be supplemented by adopting a market
part of sustainable product chain management, companies orientation, as represented by the selection of policy instru-
should use LCA of product’s environmental impacts and, on ments and a focus on cooperation between industry, policy
that basis, perform eco-design, as discussed in the following makers, consumers and other stakeholders. Because of its
subsection. Altogether, these activities should contribute to scope (25 countries of the EU) and ambitious objectives
increasing the efficiency of industrial processes and decreasing (‘‘to support sustainable development by reducing the negative
their pressure on the environment. environmental impacts of products throughout their life-cycle’’
[19]), the IPP can potentially have a large impact on how prod-
4.2. Incremental improvement through eco-design ucts are manufactured, consumed and disposed of on a world-
wide basis. Its impacts will not finish at the EU borders, as
Making consumption ‘‘reasonable’’ and organising proper currently products are manufactured and consumed globally.
end-of-life management of products have to be complemented If the IPP (and, by extension, any other product-oriented
with relevant product innovation and improvement. This environmental policy) is to follow the implications from eco-
focuses on reducing the environmental impacts throughout logical economics and industrial ecology, it should conform to
product life-cycles and, in particular, on facilitating their three elementary objectives discussed in the previous sections.
end-of-life management. More environmentally friendly They are summarised in Table 3, along with more detailed
J. Kronenberg / Journal of Cleaner Production 15 (2007) 557e566 563

Table 3
Policy implications for the IPP
Objective Strategy Examples of instruments
Make Reduce material Appeal to reason, instead of emotions Educate consumers
consumption consumption
Influence beliefs, attitudes and expectation of Support the development of LCA and eco-design, as
‘‘reasonable’’ Consume function not consumers related to sustainable consumption carriers of information
matter
Enhance information flows among Differentiated product charges
stakeholders involved in product chains
Tax consumption as part of ecological
Reduce consumption of disposable products fiscal (tax) reform
Make users pay for the environmental Set targets, e.g. regarding maximum
damage they cause through consumption resource use or recovery
Support the economy based on functionality Use consumption bans, where justified
Support dematerialisation To measure well-being, use indicators alternative to
GDP and material consumption
Promote producteservice systems (PSS)
Support the development of more
comprehensive eco-labelling programmes
(using a functional unit as a basis for comparisons,
instead of narrow product groups)
Restrict certain marketing practices

Provide for efficient systems of product Create favourable regulatory climate Organise product take-back schemes
take-back and end-of-life management for the use of wastes (end-of-life products)
Support the development of deposit-refund
Change existing systems so that products schemes
are returned, reused, remanufactured,
Support industrial ecological initiatives
recycled or incinerated with energy recovery
regarding waste management
(in this descending order of preferability,
where economically and environmentally justified) Set minimum recycled content standards
Support extended producer responsibility (EPR) Set recovery and recycling targets
Support sustainable product chain management Support the development of LCA and eco-design,
as facilitators of end-of-life product management
Support the development of product-oriented
environmental management systems (POEMS)
Discourage/prohibit exporting hazardous end-of-life
products to countries which do not have facilities
to manage them properly

Improve products through eco-design Increase the durability and functionality Support the development of LCA and eco-design,
of products as tools for product improvement
Make products easier to disassemble and recycle Green public procurement
Producer and consumer education

strategies on how to reach them and policy instruments that related to the broader systems within which they occur, the
can be used for this purpose. These objectives should be com- IPP should also be explicitly tied to the forthcoming EU the-
plied with in a descending hierarchical order; however, the matic strategy on the sustainable use of resources, to provide
simultaneous application of all of them would bring the decision makers with a complete picture of the environmental
most successful results. Together, they refer to extending impacts of consumption choices made by consumers. Seeking
the environmental responsibility of consumers (objective 1) to understand as much as possible can, to some extent, reduce
and producers (objectives 1, 2 and 3). our ignorance. Thus, studying economyeenvironment interac-
Adopting an integrated, interdisciplinary and holistic tions, following the holistic and interdisciplinary approach as
approach to analysing and shaping economyeenvironment described above with the use of tools such as material flow
interactions emerges as the most important issue. Primarily, accounting (MFA) and inputeoutput analysis in particular,
one has always to analyse products and the economic processes can help to put the IPP in a perspective of those interactions.
related to them with reference to the ecosystem in which the The main problem with the IPP is that it fails to adopt
economy is embedded. Thus, as all phenomena should be a fully integrated, systems perspective. As such, the IPP risks
564 J. Kronenberg / Journal of Cleaner Production 15 (2007) 557e566

not being able to satisfy the overarching criterion of any envi- to analyse all of the potential indirect impacts. The examples
ronmental policy e environmental effectiveness. This clearly of complex products (such as cars, refrigerators, telephones
indicates the need for system innovation rather than incremen- and computers) clearly indicate the need for further policy in-
tal product improvements, which was already argued for, e.g. tegration and for the inclusion of product-oriented environ-
by Jackson [20] and Nuij [21]. Because of its failure to address mental issues into other types of policies, seemingly
products from an holistic, systems perspective, the IPP irrelevant to products. The latter, e.g. spatial planning or edu-
addresses the objective of making consumption ‘‘reasonable’’ cational policies, should address the issues of social structure
in only a very limited way. Indeed, as the European Commis- that emerged with the rising popularity of complex products.
sion [22] clarified, the IPP ‘‘is not attempting to reduce con- Using a functional unit as a point of reference during product
sumption; rather, it is seeking to reduce the environmental comparisons, may also lead to the conclusion that the very
impact of increased consumption’’. Some authors (e.g. [5,20]) same need can be satisfied more effectively with another,
have already noted that the main disadvantage of the IPP is more environmentally friendly product or service.
that it fails to curb consumption. Instead, it transfers the policy As the IPP sets out to change consumption patterns, its task
makers’ attention, from limiting consumption to more envi- should include not only shifting from less to more environ-
ronmentally friendly consumption that is probably going to mentally friendly products, but also principally shifting into
increase when markets are created for more environmentally more environmentally friendly consumption patterns in gen-
friendly products. This certainly fails to meet the ecological eral. Instead of focusing on creating markets for environ-
economics and industrial ecology recommendations related mentally friendly products, the IPP should rather promote
to the scale of the economic activity versus the scale of the functional thinking and consequently, again, the idea of ‘‘rea-
surrounding ecosystem, and thus obeying the Earth’s carrying sonable’’ consumption. Eventually, this would lead to the
capacity. However trivial this conclusion may seem, it is a prin- transformation of the economy towards being service- (or
cipal drawback of the IPP, negating its claim to be integrated. functionality-) based, rather than being product-based (already
If we were to restrict material consumption, people would argued also by other EU institutions [24,25]). In this regard,
have to be offered a substitute way of satisfying their needs re- the IPP should link to concepts such as producteservice
lated to social life and self-esteem that are currently associated systems (PSS), which permit consumers to benefit from the
with the ownership of products. Even though reducing demand services delivered by products, while their ownership is re-
seems unlikely, indicating to companies alternative ways of tained by producers or other specialised agents.
achieving profits should be part of the IPP, which so far it If markets for green products are to be promoted, they
has failed to provide. Restricting certain marketing practices, should serve as a replacement for traditional markets, rather
especially advertising appealing to emotions, might be partic- than exist alongside them. Altogether, indirect manipulation
ularly important in the case of shaping consumer attitudes. In of products with prices may prove an efficient strategy to
a similar vein, attempts to make consumption ‘‘reasonable’’ reduce throughput. In the case when consumers’ ignorance of
have been made in terms of restricting advertising directed economyeenvironment interactions persists, economic reason-
at children, restricting advertising of certain products and re- ing has to be addressed through increasing prices on ‘‘environ-
stricting advertising using subliminal communications. Direct mentally unfriendly’’ consumption options and thus making
restrictions should be imposed on misleading advertising re- people seek alternative means of satisfying their needs.
ferring to the environmental characteristics of products, as Supporting the development of LCA also plays an important
has already been noted in the IPP. role from the point of view of satisfying all three objectives.
Learning and information sharing can lead to ‘‘reasonable’’ In the case of products the consumption of which cannot be
consumption. Our dependence on the well-being of ecosys- avoided or substituted with services, proper take-back and
tems has to be factored into consumer decisions. Once con- end-of-life management should be ensured, so that their
sumers become aware of the link between their consumption wastes are managed in an environmentally sound way. This
patterns (including issues such as consuming energy and ser- requires increasing the diversity of industrial organisms and,
vices) and the environmental problems about which they hear especially, creating niches to deal with waste materials that
in the news, their consumption is likely to become more so far have been left out of the economic process, and as
‘‘reasonable’’. Thus, reducing the ignorance of consumers such constituted a source of pollution. To support such a devel-
emerges as a particularly important component of the IPP, opment, another paradigm shift needs to take place e product
and LCA can potentially best serve to satisfy this objective. life-cycles should not be perceived as unidirectional but as
Among other things, consumers have to be aware that long- cyclic, as are life-cycles in nature.
lived products appearing in the market only constitute 6 per Finally, the above strategies should be complemented with
cent of resources extracted from the environment, but they relevant product innovation and improvement. More environ-
require the other 94 per cent which are not reflected in the mentally friendly (durable and functional) products will satisfy
system of market transactions [23]. Information should also consumer needs more efficiently and, thus, less of them will be
be used wherever possible to justify the use of other instru- necessary. Also, the IPP should require that products are
ments, such as ecological fiscal reform. designed in such a way that they could better be used by a com-
When analysing a product, it is always necessary to view munity, a rental (or leasing) company or another PSS-type of
the whole system within which it is used, and also to attempt organisation, and not only by an individual user.
J. Kronenberg / Journal of Cleaner Production 15 (2007) 557e566 565

To sum up, out of the three objectives for the IPP formu- stakeholders to behave in a ‘‘reasonable’’, rather than in
lated on the basis of theoretical implications from ecological a more abstract ‘‘sustainable’’, way.
economics and industrial ecology, the IPP in its current form In practice, relying on information alone seems unlikely to
explicitly addresses only the least significant one, that of incre- change consumer behaviour, just as it is unlikely that referring
mental product improvement. The second most important to moral or ethical considerations would change it. Thus, it has
issue, organising proper end-of-life management of products to be complemented by referring to economic reasoning
is addressed in the IPP only to a limited extent; and the most through the use of economic instruments, similar to those en-
crucial one e making consumption ‘‘reasonable’’ e has forced in an attempt to make production more sustainable.
been left out of this policy framework. Eventually, ‘‘reasonable’’ consumption cannot be viewed in
separation from ‘‘reasonable’’ production. Efforts should be
6. Conclusions made to involve business in promoting ‘‘reasonable’’ con-
sumption, and to encourage consumers to demand ‘‘reason-
Sustainable consumption and production have become im- able’’ production.
portant, as they concretise the overall principle of sustainable
development. Dealing with consumption is more ambitious, as Acknowledgements
it has been less emphasised in policy making so far. Moreover,
sustainable consumption means not only consuming more en- I am deeply indebted to Professor John Proops and Dr
vironmentally friendly products, but also changing consump- Ralph Winkler, the discussions with whom have largely con-
tion patterns. The latter tends to be overlooked in most tributed to the writing of this article. Also, I would like to
policy documents, but a strong case has been made for it in thank the referees for their valuable comments.
this article. If consumption patterns were guided by reason,
taking into consideration long-term interests of the economy, References
less material products would be consumed and to a larger ex-
[1] Max-Neef M. Human scale development: conception, application and
tent function would become the subject of market transactions.
further reflections. New York, NY: Apex Press; 1991.
This would have to be complemented by ‘‘reasonable’’ pro- [2] Max-Neef M. Economic growth and quality of life: a threshold hypoth-
duction strategies, such as organising proper end-of-life man- esis. Ecological Economics 1995;15(2):115e8.
agement of products and eco-design. [3] Lintott J. Beyond the economics of more: the place of consumption in
However, not all of the above objectives are incorporated ecological economics. Ecological Economics 1998;25(3):239e48.
into the major policy initiatives supposed to promote sustain- [4] Jackson T, Marks N. Consumption, sustainable welfare and human
needs e with reference to UK expenditure patterns between 1954 and
able consumption and production, such as the IPP. This con- 1994. Ecological Economics 1999;28(3):421e41.
firms what van der Straaten and Ugelow [26] remarked: [5] Mont O. Institutionalisation of sustainable consumption patterns based
‘‘environmental policy is the prisoner of all other policies of on shared use. Ecological Economics 2004;50(1e2):135e53.
social and economic affairs, to which higher priority is given’’. [6] Kronenberg J. Ecological economics and industrial ecology e a case
The best example of this problem is related to the potential re- study of the integrated product policy of the European Union. PhD thesis.
Lodz, Poland: University of Lodz; 2005.
duction of production that ‘‘is not even considered as a possible [7] Ayres RU, Kneese AV. Production, consumption, and externalities.
variable for achieving environmental policy, for most would American Economic Review 1969;59(3):282e97.
consider increased production as potentially increased in- [8] Costanza R, Cumberland J, Daly H, Goodland R, Norgaard R. An intro-
come’’. This happens despite the attempts for integration duction to ecological economics. Boca Raton, FL: St. Lucie Press; 1997.
[9] Faber M, Proops JLR, Baumgärtner S. All production is joint production e
and despite an increase in the declaratory support for sustain-
a thermodynamic analysis. In: Faucheux S, Gowdy S, Nicola€ı I, editors.
able development. Fundamental neglect of the biophysical Sustainability and firms. Cheltenham, UK and Lyme, US: Edward Elgar;
considerations common to ecological economics and industrial 1998. p. 131e58.
ecology (limits to growth, resources are not created ex nihilo, [10] Opschoor JB. Institutional change and development towards sustainabil-
man-made capital cannot substitute for natural capital, ‘‘all ity. In: Costanza R, Segura O, Martinez-Alier J, editors. Getting down to
production is joint production’’), are so widely spread and so earth: practical applications of ecological economics. Washington, DC:
Island Press; 1996. p. 327e50.
deeply rooted in the tradition of policy making that policy [11] Faber M, Manstetten R, Proops JLR. Humankind and the environment:
makers remain deaf to them, even when words referring to an anatomy of surprise and ignorance. Environmental Values 1992;
these issues come out of their own mouths. 1(3):217e41.
Similarly, environmental policies are affected by the con- [12] Oosterhuis F, Rubik F, Scholl G. Product policy in Europe: new environ-
flicting interests of the various stakeholders who participate mental perspectives. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers; 1996.
[13] Reisch LA. Sustainable consumption as a consumer policy issue. In:
in their development. Both of these problems are particularly Reisch LA, Røpke I, editors. The ecological economics of consump-
important from the point of view of product-oriented environ- tion. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, US: Edward Elgar;
mental policies, as they strive to influence the relationships 2004. p. 175e89.
between market actors. Differing influences of various stake- [14] Meadows DH. Leverage points: places to intervene in a system. Hartland,
holders, affected by their short- to medium-term economic VT: The Sustainability Institute; 1999.
[15] Faber M, Manstetten R, Proops JLR. Toward an open future: ignorance,
or political orientation prevent compliance with the theoretical novelty and evolution. In: Costanza R, Norton BG, Haskell BD, editors.
implications from ecological economics and industrial ecol- Ecosystem health: new goals for environmental management. Washing-
ogy. Indeed, it should be easier to convince various ton, DC: Island Press; 1992. p. 72e96.
566 J. Kronenberg / Journal of Cleaner Production 15 (2007) 557e566

[16] Ritzer G. Enchanting a disenchanted world. Revolutionizing the means IP/03/858]. Brussels: Commission of the European Communities;
of consumption. Thousand Oaks, CA: Pine Forge Press; 1999. 2003.
[17] Princen T. Consumption and its externalities: where economy meets ecol- [23] Ayres RU, Kneese AV. Externalities: economics and thermodynamics.
ogy. Global Environmental Politics 2001;1(3):11e30. In: Archibugi F, Nijkamp P, editors. Economy and ecology: towards
[18] Lorek S. Indicators for environmentally sound household consumption. sustainable development. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers;
In: Hertwich E, editor. Life-cycle approaches to sustainable consump- 1989. p. 89e118.
tion. Laxenburg: IIASA; 2002. p. 139e52 [IIASA Interim Report [24] European Parliament. Report on the communication from the commis-
IR-02-073]. sion to the council and the European Parliament on integrated product
[19] European Commission. Questions and answers on integrated product policy [FINAL A5e0261/2004]. Brussels: Committee on the Environ-
policy (IPP) [MEMO/03/136]. Brussels: Commission of the European ment, Public Health and Consumer Policy; 2004.
Communities; 2003. [25] Council of the European Union. Integrated product policy e council
[20] Jackson T. Book review. Journal of Industrial Ecology 1999;3 conclusions [Document no. 14405/03]. Brussels: General Secretariat of
(2e3):181e3. the Council; 2003.
[21] Nuij R. Eco-innovation: helped or hindered by Integrated Product Policy. [26] van der Straaten J, Ugelow J. Environmental policy in the Netherlands:
Journal of Sustainable Product Design 2001;1(1):49e51. change and effectiveness. In: Wintle M, Reeve R, editors. Rhetoric and
[22] European Commission. Integrated product policy: commission reality in environmental policy. Aldershot, UK and Brookfield, US:
outlines its strategy to stimulate greener products [Press release Ashgate; 1994.

You might also like