Insights from behavioural economics for forest economics and environmental policy: Potential nudges to encourage woodland creation for climate change mitigation and adaptation? by Gregory Valatin; Darren Moseley; Norman Dandy

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 10

FORPOL-01413; No of Pages 10

Forest Policy and Economics xxx (2016) xxx–xxx

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Forest Policy and Economics

journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/forpol

Insights from behavioural economics for forest economics and environmental policy:
Potential nudges to encourage woodland creation for climate change mitigation
and adaptation?
Gregory Valatin a,⁎, Darren Moseley b, Norman Dandy c,1
a
Forest Research, Alice Holt Lodge, Farnham, Surrey GU10 4LH, UK
b
Forest Research, Northern Research Station, Roslin, Midlothian EH25 9SY, UK
c
Centre for Rural Policy Research, University of Exeter, Lazenby Building, St Germans Road, Exeter EX4 4PJ, UK

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Evidence from behavioural economics illustrates how cognitive factors can affect the preferences, values and
Received 5 June 2015 choices of individual decision-makers. The evidence also shows how policy ‘nudges’ that account for the influ-
Received in revised form 23 December 2015 ence of cognitive factors can shift choices in socially desirable directions. Despite a wide range of potential appli-
Accepted 26 March 2016
cations, little research has been published to date applying behavioural economics in forestry. As an example of
Available online xxxx
how behavioural economics could be used, this paper considers the potential for nudges in encouraging wood-
Keywords:
land creation to help meet climate change mitigation and adaptation goals. Although forests offer significant cli-
Nudge mate change mitigation and adaptation potential, land managers are often reluctant to create new woodlands,
Behavioural economics hindering accomplishment of national targets. Nudges could potentially help overcome the barriers. Disaggregat-
Environmental economics ing behavioural elements of woodland creation using the Stages of Change model, we identify a number of rele-
Afforestation vant intervention points at which nudges could be applied. It is argued that nudges may best be tailored towards
Public policy different types of land manager taking account of differences in attitudes, motivations, circumstances and
Climate change behaviour. To be effective, a combination with other policy instruments is likely to be needed. Pilot studies are
recommended in determining which nudges are cost-effective. The paucity of existing studies drawing upon be-
havioural economics, or testing out nudges, points to this as a current frontier of both forest economics and pol-
icy, but can also be considered a frontier of environmental policy more widely. Developing a consistent valuation
framework allowing for the social endogeneity of preferences and for optimization (or some other protocol) to be
used in selecting policy options remains a fundamental challenge.
Crown Copyright © 2016 Published by Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction influenced by cognitive, ethical, and behavioural factors – including


knowledge of emissions and acceptability of carbon offsetting (Torres
Calls have been made to extend the boundaries of forest economics et al., 2013); results indicating how harvesting and resource levels can
(e.g. Kant, 2003), including to account for findings from behavioural depend on heterogeneity of forest owners' preferences and objectives
economics (Knetsch, 2005; Shogren, 2007; Kant et al., 2013). However, (Rinaldi et al., 2015); results indicating the relative importance of large-
studies linking behavioural economics and forest economics and policy ly non-market forest ecosystem services (social, cultural, and land use
remain sparse. Existing studies include: evidence of other-regarding related activities) compared to financial rewards from a study of life
preferences of villagers in India (Shahi and Kant, 2013; Kumar and satisifaction among First Nations in Canada (Kant et al., in this issue);
Kant, in this issue); results pointing to potential counter-productive evidence from Finland on potential to reduce forest policy costs and in-
long-term effects of incentive programs aimed at increasing forest crease ecosystem service provision by shaping written communications
cover due to behavioural feedbacks, suggesting social learning and my- through cognitive appeal to positive subjective experience such as hap-
opic decision-making can be important (Henderson et al., 2013); evi- piness or goodness, and cognitive optimality to increase the ease with
dence from Mexico indicating that valuation of forest carbon offsets is which people can imagine and simulate the text (Matthies et al., 2016).
Building upon and developing earlier work on insights from behav-
ioural economics for ecosystem services valuation and sustainability
⁎ Corresponding author.
E-mail address: Gregory.Valatin@forestry.gsi.gov.uk (G. Valatin).
(Moseley and Valatin, 2013) and policy nudges (Moseley et al., 2014),
1
Current address: The Plunkett Foundation, The Quadrangle, Woodstock, Oxfordshire this paper explores some of the implications of behavioural economics
OX20 1LH, UK. for forestry economics and environmental policy. Noting the

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2016.06.012
1389-9341/Crown Copyright © 2016 Published by Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

Please cite this article as: Valatin, G., et al., Insights from behavioural economics for forest economics and environmental policy: Potential nudges
to encourage woodland creation..., Forest Policy and Economics (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2016.06.012
2 G. Valatin et al. / Forest Policy and Economics xxx (2016) xxx–xxx

importance of forests in meeting current climate change mitigation and process of making choices and influenced by others (cf. Bromley,
adaptation challenges, the potential for applying policy nudges to en- 2008; Laband, 2013), with choices dependent on the choice set in
courage woodland creation is focused on as a case study. which they are embedded (Sunstein, 2000). It would also need to
We begin by exploring some of the implications of behavioural eco- allow the use of optimization or another protocol (e.g. ‘satisficing’,
nomics for forestry economics and policy. This is followed by a section cost-effectiveness in ensuring safe minimum standards, or in pursuing
reviewing existing evidence on policy nudges – a form of instrument a rights-based approach) to select policy options.
that draws on insights from behavioural economics, outlining evidence Developing a consistent framework that allows for the social
on their application in a range of contexts. The fourth section applies endogeneity of preferences could provide a sounder foundation to un-
these insights to a forestry case study, including background on barriers derpin the rationale for interventions to steer and shape markets (cf.
to woodland creation, and considers potential for nudges to help over- Umpfenbach, 2014). It could also be more consistent with pursuit of
come these. This is followed by a discussion of some theoretical consid- sustainability goals (Gowdy, 2004) and some existing strands of
erations, practical and ethical issues relating to application of nudges. policy-making. Endogenous preferences are more consistent with
Our concluding remarks then briefly reflect on insights from behaviour- behaviour change perspectives such as in public health, for instance
al economics as a research frontier for forest economics and environ- (e.g. that reducing the incidence of obesity requires altering preferences
mental policy. and behaviour). Similarly, tackling problems such as global climate
change and biodiversity loss are argued to require changing behaviour
2. Insights from behavioural economics and social norms, which may then also lead to changes in values as
new norms of behaviour become internalised (Kinzig et al., 2013).
Evidence from behavioural economics illustrates how a variety of Behavioural change perspectives may seem anomalous to those
cognitive factors and biases can affect choices (e.g. Groeneveld, 2010; used to basing economic analysis upon consumer sovereignty. Howev-
Hoehn et al., 2010; Pearson et al., 2012). These include effects of infor- er, they have the advantage of recognising that personal preferences
mation processing such as complexity, familiarity and salience; effects are not invariant and that cognitive factors can lead to systematic biases
associated with information presentation such as format and framing; which can inadvertently result in some behaviours that harm the
contextual factors including anchoring, hypothetical bias, setting and interests of the individual concerned, as well as those of wider society.
reference state, as well as learning. The perspective that decisions are Meeting societal goals such as national carbon emission reduction tar-
constrained by the individual's ability to obtain and process information gets, for example, is increasingly recognised as feasible only if people
(‘bounded rationality’) differs from the standard conception of ‘rational’ change their behaviour – especially those responsible for the most
decision-making conventional in economics by considering the influ- environmentally-damaging activities. Understanding how to change
ence of cognitive factors including mental short-cuts (e.g. rules of behaviour is therefore a concern of government in order to ensure
thumb) and habits in shaping preferences. policy success (House of Lords, 2011).
Behavioural economics insights could be viewed as critical for some The next section considers existing evidence on use of a type of
key elements of forestry economics and environmental policy. For policy instrument (‘nudges’) that aim to change behaviour by drawing
example, cognitive factors can influence the level of non-market on insights from behavioural economics.
values for ecosystem services estimated using stated preference
techniques (Table 1), and also their variance (Table 2). Although 3. Policy nudges
the extent to which different impacts are additive is unclear, the evi-
dence summarised in the Tables suggests that cognitive factors can Policy ‘nudges’, are a means of encouraging, or guiding behaviour
affect stated values by an order of magnitude in some cases. (Halpern, 2015). They aim to influence people's decisions without elim-
Of the different cognitive factors, framing is fundamental in under- inating options, or appreciably altering their relative costs (Thaler and
pinning how forestry economics is analysed and policy conceptualised. Sunstein, 2008).
It shapes how problems are defined, causes diagnosed, remedies Nudges influence choices as a consequence of bounded rationality,
suggested, moral judgements are made (Entman, 1993), and whether or cognitive biases. Hausman and Welch (2010), for example, consider
solutions proposed are viewed as feasible to solve, or too complex or in- that nudges “are called for because of flaws in individual decision-
tractable. It also shapes the findings of theoretical analyses. (An example making, and they work by making use of those flaws”. 3
of how adoption of a safe minimum standards approach instead of un- Nudges can shift choices in socially desirable directions (Thaler and
constrained maximisation one can reverse results in a game theory Sunstein, 2008). They are attractive within a policy context because
model of international environmental agreements, can be found in they can be perceived as relatively unobtrusive influences on individual
Valatin (2005)). There appears relatively little evidence at present on decision making. A benefit of using the approach is that (unlike regula-
the impact of framing on the effectiveness of environmental policies, al- tion) it is not compulsory and does not require additional financial in-
though potentially critical to their adoption and success (Nisbet, 2009; centives or disincentives. Consequently, policy nudges have potential
Umpfenbach, 2014), and a focus of some analysis of media reports to offer a cost-effective approach that may be used in as an alternative
(e.g. Corbett, 2015; O'Neill et al., 2015) and social media (Jang and to, or often, alongside, more traditional ‘carrots’ and ‘sticks’.
Hart, 2015). Nudge has been promoted in the United States as sitting between
The influence of cognitive factors on values poses a number of state interventionism and market driven norms (Selinger and Whyte,
important challenges at a theoretical level both for forestry and for 2012). It was taken up by the UK Government through the formation
environmental economics and policy more widely. For example, once in 2010 of the Behavioural Insights Team (BIT) with a remit to find ‘in-
individual preferences are recognised as dynamic, partly formed telligent ways to encourage, support, and enable people to make better
through interactions with others (e.g. Kant, 2003) and social moulding choices for themselves’ (BIT, 2010a). BIT has applied behavioural ap-
(Atkinson et al., 2012), rather than essentially fixed as traditionally as- proaches to a range of policy areas, including health, environmental be-
sumed in economics, optimality becomes difficult to define (Costanza, haviour, consumer empowerment, crime, fraud, debt and error. Some
2004).2 This poses a fundamental challenge to mainstream economics approaches combine regulation, incentives and nudges such as social
to develop a consistent framework. This would need to allow for the so-
cial endogeneity of preferences – that values are formed partly in the 3
Much evidence on different biases exists, but the extent to which bounded rationality
per se is flawed remains disputed. Levine et al. (2015), for example, argue that bounded
2
Entman (1993) notes a similar challenge relating to framing in gauging “true” public rationality is fundamental to an empirically realistic characterization of humans as effi-
opinion. cient complexity managers.

Please cite this article as: Valatin, G., et al., Insights from behavioural economics for forest economics and environmental policy: Potential nudges
to encourage woodland creation..., Forest Policy and Economics (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2016.06.012
G. Valatin et al. / Forest Policy and Economics xxx (2016) xxx–xxx 3

Table 1
Influence of cognitive factors on stated non-market values.

Category Cognitive factor Aspect Impact on value Key references

Information Familiarity Awareness of threatened status of species 68% if aware versus 40% if unaware White et al. (2001)
processing (proportion of respondents willing to pay a
stated amount)
Salience Charismatic species used as a proxy for 6 times higher White et al. (2001)
biodiversity value
Information Format Textual compared to tabular information 2.5 to 4 times higher Hoehn et al. (2010)
presentation (acreage of new habitat considered
sufficient to compensate for lost habitat)
Framing Structural species groups compared to 2 times higher Milon and Scrogin (2006)
functional description (e.g. water levels)
Named species compared to a group of five 1.7 to 1.8 times higher marginal rate of Jacobsen et al. (2008)
unnamed species substitution
Label effect 1.3 times higher when ‘National Park’ label Czajkowski and Hanley (2009)
used
Context Anchoring One question (‘single-bound’) compared to 1.3 times higher Flachaire and Hollard (2006)
(starting point bias) initial question with follow-up
(‘double-bound’) choice experiment
Single choice experiment compared to a series 1.3 to 2.7 times higher Groeneveld (2010)
of choice experiments
Hypothetical bias Lack of payment mechanism compared to 2 to 10 times higher Macmillan et al. (2002)
expectation of payment based upon response
Setting Individual compared to group values 3.5 times higher Macmillan et al. (2002),
Kaplowitz and Hoehn (2001)
Citizen compared to individual values 2.1 to 2.4 times higher Ovaskainen and Kniivila (2005)
Reference state Initial question on environmental beliefs and 1.8 times higher Pouta (2004)
values
Learning Discussion with friends and family 1.2 times higher Macmillan et al. (2002)
Lexicographic Protest votes Median 3 times lower Dziegielewska and
preferences Mendelsohn (2007); Pearson
et al. (2012)

norms, e.g. smoking cessation – banning smoking in public places, in- None of the published applications reviewed below relate to forest-
centives to quit smoking, and increasing social unacceptability of ry. However, some relate to wider environmental policies such as reduc-
smoking. ing energy consumption and encouraging recycling.
As nudges can have short-term effects and often do not actively The EAST (Easy, Attractive, Social, Timely) framework (Table 3) – the
engage the individual, three related approaches have also been pro- approach currently used in the UK by BIT, is adopted in presenting evi-
posed: ‘Steer’ (Grist, 2010) enables individuals to understand better dence below.
how humans make judgements, empowering them to steer their in-
stinctive (automatic) behaviour, through learned habits, towards 3.1.1. Easy - making it easier to do things
better decisions; ‘Ask’ (Ampt and Ashton-Graham, 2013) engages
the target audience to articulate their objectives and the behaviours 3.1.1.1. Defaults. Many people tend to accept pre-set options (Dolan
they can adopt to achieve these (the ‘ask’ element); ‘Think’ (John et al., 2012). Thus, providing options that benefit both the individual
et al., 2009) asserts that citizens, given the right context and framing, and society seems sensible. For example, changing from ‘opt-in’ to an
can think themselves collectively towards a better understanding of ‘opt-out’ scheme can significantly increase employee savings in pension
the problems and solutions. plans (Halpern, 2015), with one study in the United States finding the
impact to more than double (from 37% to 86%) in enrolment of recently
recruited employees (Madrian and Shea, 2001). Similarly, countries
3.1. Evidence on nudges where individuals are required to opt-out of organ donation are report-
ed to have far higher organ donation rates than those where they opt-in
The United States and the UK have pioneered the application of be- (Johnson and Goldstein, 2003).
havioural economics to policy (although other countries have also
made a number of innovative applications) and consequently are the 3.1.1.2. Simplification. UK tax letters written in plain English starting
source of much of the evidence on the application of nudges. with a simple request have been found by BIT often to be 2 or 3 times
The evidence summarised below comes primarily from randomised as effective as the standard letters previously. Simply including a web-
control trials (RCTs). These compare the response of a group subject to link to the online tax form increased tax return completion by 22%
an ‘intervention’ with a ‘control’ group. (Halpern, 2015).

Table 2
Influence of cognitive factors on the variance of stated non-market values.

Category Cognitive factor Aspect Impact on variance Key references

Information processing Complexity Use of overarching scenarios or simpler 8 times higher for more complex formats Breffle and Rowe (2002);
resource-specific trade-offs DeShazo and Fermo (2002)
Information presentation Format Textual compared to tabular information 2 times higher Hoehn et al. (2010)
(acreage of new habitat considered sufficient
to compensate for lost habitat)
Learning Workshop discussion compared to no Reduce Christie et al. (2006)
discussion

Please cite this article as: Valatin, G., et al., Insights from behavioural economics for forest economics and environmental policy: Potential nudges
to encourage woodland creation..., Forest Policy and Economics (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2016.06.012
4 G. Valatin et al. / Forest Policy and Economics xxx (2016) xxx–xxx

Table 3
Categorisation of behavioural economics elements into Easy, Attractive, Social and Timely groups.
Source: Halpern (2013).

Easy Defaults Simplification Remove friction


Attractive Salience Messenger Personalisation Affect Incentive design
Social Norms Networks Reciprocity Active commitments Eyes & faces
Timely Priming Framing Key moments

As form filling is unpopular, pre-populating them can encourage increased by 0.2 to 0.4 standard deviations — impacts comparable to re-
completion, while also saving time and reducing errors. Pre- ducing class sizes by over one third (Fryer et al., 2012).
populating application forms and providing help to complete them
led to an increase in college enrolment rates for students from
lower income families in two US states increasing from 34% to 42% 3.1.3. Social (tell people what others are doing)
(Bettinger et al., 2012).
3.1.3.1. Social norms. We are strongly influenced by what others do
3.1.1.3. Remove friction. There has been very low uptake of loft insulation (Dolan et al., 2012). Describing what most people are doing (descrip-
schemes in the UK despite large subsidies and information demonstrat- tive norms) makes people explicitly aware of other people's good
ing that insulation pays for itself within months. A barrier was the hassle behaviour and has been demonstrated to be effective in encouraging
of clearing an attic before it can be insulated. When insulation firms of- recycling, energy and water efficiency, and reducing littering
fered to clear the lofts and dispose of unwanted junk at cost, there was a (Schultz et al., 2007).
fivefold increase in uptake even though this meant the customer paid There is evidence that there is an even greater effect when referring
more (BIT, 2011). to the social norm of a particular area. For example, publicising the fact
that 9 out of 10 people in their local area pay their taxes on time led to a
3.1.2. Attractive (make messages stand out and choices attractive) 15% increase in payment of taxes in that area of Britain (BIT, 2012).
A RCT of 600,000 households in the United States, where residents
3.1.2.1. Salience. Redesigning forms to make them clearer and highlight- were supplied with a report comparing their energy use and CO2 emis-
ing key messages helps to draw people's attention to important sions with their neighbours, found energy consumption decreased by
information, or actions required of them. This approach was applied 2.0% (Allcott, 2011). Reductions in energy consumption have continued
alongside social norms to increase tax compliance by doctors and den- to be sustained over time (Ayres et al., 2009).
tists in the UK, increasing responses by 14%. These voluntary disclo-
sures, which reduced the need for follow-up letters were worth over 3.1.3.2. Networks. A trial in two Greater London local authorities tested
£1 million (BIT, 2012). the effect of varying levels of discount for energy efficiency products,
depending on how many people opt in to the offer. Alongside introduc-
ing a small financial incentive, the aim was to create a signal that others
3.1.2.2. Messenger. Who communicates information can strongly influ-
are taking up the offer and form a social norm. Discounts increased from
ence individuals. The Department of Energy & Climate Change (DECC)
10% for two households, to 15% for three households and 25% for five
sets up a network of local energy efficiency ‘champions’, who would
households, thus giving people incentives to encourage others in their
commit to promoting the benefits of energy efficiency improvements
local community to take up the offer with them (BIT, 2011).
within their community (BIT, 2011) prior to launching the ‘Green
Deal’, an initiative to help people make energy saving improvements
3.1.3.3. Commitment (and exemplify). BIT, the National Health Service
to their homes. These champions were deemed to have increased com-
and Boots UK (a major retail chemist) developed a smoking cessation
munity engagement and a desire to know more about energy efficiency
programme that combined incentives to stop smoking with a commit-
and community renewable projects (DECC, 2014).
ment in the form of a signed ‘contract’ whereby participants keep or
lose rewards depending on whether they pass regular smoking tests.
3.1.2.3. Personalisation. Personal language in messages (e.g. adding The results suggest that people entering into a commitment with anoth-
hand-written instructions on notes to the respondent), led to a doubling er individual or group are more likely to respond in a positive way (BIT,
of response rates to questionnaires (BIT, 2012). A trial of personalised 2010b), particularly if incentivised (see also Volpp et al., 2009).
text reminders to pay fines from the Ministry of Justice that began The UK Prime Minister demonstrated the government's commit-
with the recipient's name led to a 10% increase in people making a pay- ment to reducing its own carbon emissions by requiring central govern-
ment compared to a standard text reminder. ment to cut emissions from its office estate by 10% between 14 May
2010 and 13 May 2011. The target was exceeded, with a 13.8% reduction
3.1.2.4. Affect. Decision making can be strongly affected by emotions and reported. The government then sought to reduce its emissions by a fur-
feelings of disgust are particularly strong. An advertisement to address ther 25% by 2015 (BIT, 2011).
high levels of diarrhoea in Ghana showed mothers and their children
walking out of bathrooms with a glowing purple pigment that contam- 3.1.4. Timely (make things timely and relevant and key decision-making
inated everything they touched. This created a sense of disgust and led points)
to a tripling in the percentage of people washing their hands after using
the toilet (Nudge blog, 2008). 3.1.4.1. Priming. Individuals' decisions are influenced by subconscious
cues. At a transit station in Singapore people are primed just before
3.1.2.5. Incentive design. Financial incentives to achieve better exam re- they decide between taking the stairs or the escalator. The escalator is
sults have often been found to be ineffective whether given to teachers, stationary when not in use which has two effects. The first is that the
or students (Fryer, 2011). However, harnessing loss aversion, a study in usual sound and movement is absent and the habitual attraction to-
the United States found that giving teachers financial bonuses in ad- wards the escalator is numbed. The second is that anyone unfamiliar
vance (to be paid back subsequently if higher exam results are not with the power-saving facility may think the escalator is not working.
achieved) led to large improvements in performance. Maths test scores The individual is primed into choosing the stairs over the escalator

Please cite this article as: Valatin, G., et al., Insights from behavioural economics for forest economics and environmental policy: Potential nudges
to encourage woodland creation..., Forest Policy and Economics (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2016.06.012
G. Valatin et al. / Forest Policy and Economics xxx (2016) xxx–xxx 5

and this has led to an increase in stair use at the station, saving power identified profitability of agriculture relative to forestry as one of the
and helping people develop healthy habits (iNudgeYou, 2012). three biggest barriers, along with a concern that woodland creation
would reduce the value of farm land. Financial returns can also be a
3.1.4.2. Framing. Many people assign financial decisions into different key barrier for external investors and institutional land managers
‘mental accounts’ even though this may financially disadvantage them (Lobley et al., 2012). Survey-based studies tend to identify subsidies as
(e.g. a holiday savings jar while there is an outstanding credit card a significant influence on woodland creation decisions (e.g. Eves et al.,
debt). This behaviour has been used to influence how government pay- 2014; Glynn et al., 2012), with lack of access to aid and issues related
ments to individuals are spent. Adding the label ‘Winter Fuel Payment’ to administration and design of grants potential barriers.
led to individuals being almost 14 times as likely to spend the money More profound cultural and regulatory barriers also emerge from
on fuel than had their incomes been increased in other ways (Beatty the evidence. In particular, studies have consistently revealed a strong
et al., 2011). resistance amongst farmers to the conversion of land from food produc-
tion to forestry (Burton, 2004; Duesberg et al., 2013; Neumann and
3.1.4.3. Key moments. In some countries welfare payments (conditional Krogman, 2007; Watkins et al., 1996). This resistance manifests itself
cash transfers) have been used to encourage school attendance. Under in many ways, which themselves can be encountered as ‘barriers’, in-
a scheme in Bogata, Columbia, releasing a third of the extra payments cluding as the expressed desire to continue long-standing (often inter-
just prior to the start of the next academic year in December to help generational) family commitments (Neumann and Krogman, 2007),
families meet associated expenses was found to lead to school enrol- the maintenance of particular aesthetics associated with agricultural
ment rates increasing by more than 2% compared to a system of con- crop production (Burton and Wilson, 2000), and in the near ubiquitous
stant bi-monthly payments (Barrera-Osorio et al., 2011). belief that food production is their and their land's raison d'être. This last
factor leads to some commonly expressed perceptions such as that
4. Case study: potential for nudges to encourage woodland creation? there is a lack of ‘spare’ land for tree planting (e.g. Eves et al., 2014),
that the land is ‘too good’ for trees (e.g. Bell, 1999), and that allowing
4.1. Woodlands and climate change mitigation and adaptation woodland to regenerate is to ‘abandon’ the land. Furthermore, the
time scales intrinsic to forestry are at odds with the annual cycles em-
Woodlands offer significant climate change mitigation and adapta- bedded within farming culture (Burton and Wilson, 2000). Some
tion potential – including reducing downstream flood risk (Nisbet farmers state they would not plant trees on their land even if forestry
et al., 2015) within the context of increasing extreme weather events. were shown to be more profitable than other land-uses (Duesberg
Nationally (and globally), woodlands are an important component et al., 2013).
of strategies to sequester carbon (Canadell and Raupach, 2008) as Regulation can generate further inter-linked ‘barriers’ to woodland
recognised, for example, in Article 5 of the Paris Agreement of the Unit- creation. Land managers in the UK, for example, often perceive conver-
ed Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC, 2015). sion to forestry as a ‘one-way track’ in that the existing regulatory re-
Compared to a range of alternatives, existing evidence points to wood- gime ties afforested land into a cycle of growth, fell and restock –
land creation generally being a cost-effective method of climate change preventing a return to agriculture (Dandy, 2012). This potential loss of
mitigation (Valatin and Price, 2014). Forests provide a key element control (and option value) can be a ‘barrier’ to woodland creation deci-
in meeting climate change ambitions (Read et al., 2009), yet wood- sions. Second, the receipt of government grants often ties land man-
land creation is not progressing at a rate to meet these in the UK agers to providing public access, which can be unpopular and again
(Thomas et al., 2015) and in some other European countries (e.g. raises concerns about loss of control (Glynn et al., 2012).
Duesberg et al., 2013). In the UK, for instance, forest cover is gradu- In summary, there are a variety of reasons – both financial and non-
ally increasing – averaging 14,600 ha per year (an annual increase financial, why landowners and land managers are often reluctant to
of 0.5%) over the period 1900–2015 (FAO, 2015, Table 2), but the create new woodlands, hindering accomplishment of national targets
rate of increase is lower than during the 1980s (FC, 2015, Fig. 1.6). for woodland creation and climate change mitigation (Thomas et al.,
UK forests now cover more than double the area of those at the be- 2015). Although low afforestation rates are often attributed to lack of fi-
ginning of the twentieth century, but although they represent a nancial attractiveness, much evidence suggests that wider issues are
higher percentage of total land area in Scotland (18%) and Wales also at play. These include long-held cultural views amongst farming
(15%) than in England (10%) or Northern Ireland (8%), UK forest communities on what land is for which preclude changing land-use
cover (13%) remains far below EU (38%) and global (31%) means (see Watkins et al., 1996) and a perception that climate change mitiga-
(FC, 2015, Tables 1.2 and 9.1). tion and adaptation are less urgent than more imminent threats such as
Many potential interventions are likely to be relevant to woodland pests and diseases (Lawrence and Marzano, 2014). Simply providing
creation by a variety of decision-makers, including landowners, estate greater financial incentives is unlikely to be most cost-effective and
managers, tenant farmers and external investors, and for convenience, other approaches need to be considered.
subsequently they will be collectively termed ‘land managers’. We dis-
cuss the potential for tailoring nudges to distinguish between groups 4.3. Applying nudges to encourage woodland creation
in Section 5.
In considering the potential for application of nudges, it is critical to
4.2. Barriers to woodland creation acknowledge that woodland creation is not a simple, short-term behav-
iour such as making a consumer purchase. Nor is it based on the quick,
What accounts for low woodland creation rates in Europe and North intuitive or autonomous decision-making processes that, in light of dual
America? It is often farmers who manage much of the land that could be process theories (see Evans and Stanovich, 2013), many nudges are con-
used, but interest in creating woodland in this sector tends to be low sidered particularly relevant to. Rather it is a relatively complex phe-
(Lawrence and Dandy, 2014). Recent surveys have shown that around nomenon comprising multiple smaller actions and decisions, and has
two-thirds (65%) of farmers in England, for example, are unlikely to long-term repercussions.
plant forests (Eves et al., 2014) and in Scotland only 18% of farmers Nonetheless, woodland creation is underpinned by a process of
expressed any interest in planting (Stubbs, 2011). Regular efforts have awareness, consideration, interaction and decision making that offers
been made to discover the causes of this reluctance. a number of distinct opportunities for engagement (‘intervention
Although rarely the sole barrier, poor financial returns are often con- points’) where nudges of different types may be applied to influence
sidered a barrier to woodland creation. Eves et al. (2014, Figs. 4–8) land managers. It is for this reason that we draw on the Stages of Change

Please cite this article as: Valatin, G., et al., Insights from behavioural economics for forest economics and environmental policy: Potential nudges
to encourage woodland creation..., Forest Policy and Economics (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2016.06.012
6 G. Valatin et al. / Forest Policy and Economics xxx (2016) xxx–xxx

(SoC) model (Prochaska et al., 1992), a widely applied cognitive be- stakeholders to communicate the benefits of planting. They could also
haviour change model, to disaggregate the practice of woodland cre- facilitate land managers joining local woodland groups and encouraging
ation into short-term stages that may plausibly be the focus of land manager engagement with woodland creation by arranging meet-
nudges. The SoC model identifies five stages of ‘motivational readi- ings on site.
ness’: (a) precontemplation, (b) contemplation, (c) preparation,
(d) action and (e) maintenance. It is not our argument that ‘reflective’ 4.3.5. Maintenance
(Evans and Stanovich, 2013) cognitive decision-making processes do At the final stage identified by the SoC model, a primary objective is
not occur at individual stages, but only that the identification of ‘auto- to ensure appropriate ongoing management of the trees that are
matic’ processes is not possible without breaking down the concept of planted in order for woodland creation to be successful. A key nudge
woodland creation. Technically, therefore, many of the interventions here is to promote messages of sustainable forest management estab-
we describe are not ‘nudges for woodland creation’ per se, but rather po- lishing expectations for management, especially amongst local social
tential elements in a series of nudges that, in combination, may result in groups. This could even progress to individual managers being asked
woodland creation through the stimulation of the necessary component to become a woodland ‘champion’ to promote and assist woodland cre-
behaviours. A key rationale behind staged models such as SoC is that in- ation locally.
dividuals at the same stage face similar problems and barriers, and thus For the different types of nudges, some suggested applications to
can be helped by the same type of intervention. We extrapolate this to encourage woodland creation by land managers are summarised in
explore the idea that similarly staged individuals may be ready for sim- Table 4 using the EAST framework categories. In addition, some
ilar nudges. nudges might usefully target wider stakeholders and decision-
makers such as social impact investors (e.g. highlighting the climate
4.3.1. Precontemplation and wider societal benefits of creating woodlands), and local govern-
In the first stage, interventions could usefully focus on increasing in- ment officials (e.g. to shorten planning approval times for large-scale
formation both about the benefits of woodland creation and of success afforestation projects).
stories illustrating how perceived barriers such as the need for ongoing The types of nudges suggested above could be expected to help
maintenance can be readily overcome. They could promote discussions overcome many existing barriers to woodland creation, including by en-
of woodland creation amongst peer groups and networks at land man- couraging farmers to move away from culturally polarised views of
agement events, and establish accessible demonstration sites. There themselves as involved in agriculture towards considering woodland
may also be opportunities to ask individuals to make a choice about creation as one element of a more holistic view of land management.
woodland creation as part of wider application processes – such as for Land-use across any given landholding is rarely homogeneous – farmers
land management grants. This stage also offers opportunities to lay apply different objectives and decision-making criteria to different parts
the groundwork for progression in later stages. For example, seeking of their estate, often including small pockets of woodland seen as deliv-
the registration of land manager's whole land holdings during other ac- ering desirable non-market benefits. A key to effective engagement is to
tivities such as claiming agricultural subsidies would establish a useful understand how different parts of the farm contribute to the overall
baseline in considering whether to tailor nudges towards different enterprise, both economically and culturally, and hence for those de-
groups – such as those who have, or do not have, woodland on their signing nudges to try to ‘think like a farmer’ rather than a forester or
land already. For farmers in England, for example, those with existing policymaker.
woodlands, as well as those with larger farms, are apparently more like-
ly to plant new woodlands (Eves et al., 2014). Registering whole land 5. Discussion
holdings would also facilitate any subsequent grant applications to
plant new woodlands. As we saw (Section 2) cognitive factors can have large impacts on
preferences, values and choices. Cognitive factors (e.g. framing and
4.3.2. Contemplation loss aversion) shape cultural barriers to woodland creation, but can in-
In the second stage managers are especially likely to seek clarifica- fluence the way land managers' perceptions of other barriers too
tion of woodland creation benefits, often drawing on established and (Section 4). The influence of cognitive factors points to opportunities
trusted networks. As loss aversion could potentially be a key factor at for policy-makers to use instruments such as the nudges to help over-
this stage, providing simple and accessible information on grants and come the barriers.
other supports, while also stressing their time-limited nature may be
useful. Streamlining application procedures will help create a positive 5.1. Theoretical considerations
narrative about finance and administration from land manager peer
groups. Would nudges make a difference to long-term woodland cover? A
behavioural economics perspective recognising the social endogeneity
4.3.3. Preparation of preferences implies potential for multiple equilibria (or possibly a
Following a manager's decision to plant in principle, the third stage lack of long-term equilibria) is likely to be pervasive. This suggests
offers a number of opportunities for support through simple interven- that nudges, or similar interventions, could make a long-term difference
tions. For example, assisting managers in identifying available land to the overall amount of woodland. Some may argue drawing upon
and creating opportunities in relatively ‘public’ settings for them to General Equilibrium theory that nudges will not have any long-run
commit to planting new woodland. Making land registration and iden- effects as woodland cover will be determined purely by financial
tification of contractors and suppliers easy could also be especially use- returns, which provide feedback facilitating social learning. Howev-
ful for land managers in this stage. er, in a world also characterised by complexity, uneven distribution
of resources, and diverse motivations for creating woodlands,
4.3.4. Action whether financial returns alone determine the level of woodland in
The fourth stage, at which point planting takes place, is both a critical the long-run may be doubted, even in countries where subsequent
stage and the point at which the land manager may potentially be least reconversion of forests is permitted. Results from chaos theory on
involved as the ‘behaviour’ may be carried out by others (e.g. contrac- sensitive dependence to initial conditions are also worth recalling,
tors). Having said this, constructive interventions could include as these might imply that, akin to the ‘butterfly effect’ (for origins,
supporting land managers in pooling or sharing information on contrac- see: Hilborn, 2004), even a relatively minor nudge could conceivably
tors and suppliers, pre-populating grant forms, engaging other local have a large impact on long-term woodland cover. Determining the

Please cite this article as: Valatin, G., et al., Insights from behavioural economics for forest economics and environmental policy: Potential nudges
to encourage woodland creation..., Forest Policy and Economics (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2016.06.012
G. Valatin et al. / Forest Policy and Economics xxx (2016) xxx–xxx 7

Table 4
Summary of types of nudges and potential application to woodland creation by EAST category (*).

Category Nudge Behavioural insight Application to woodland creation

EASY Defaults Individuals asked to opt-out (rather than Ask land managers to register whole land holdings as the default (rather than just areas
opt-in) to schemes for which grants being currently applied).
Simplification (Format) Make it clearer and easier Ensure information is easy to understand and language is clear; pre-populate application
forms
Remove friction Identify and remove actual or perceived Identify any ‘sticking points’ in the bureaucratic and operational process of woodland
barriers creation and offer a service to deal with them
ATTRACTIVE Salience Draw attention to key points Highlight the role of woodland creation in meeting climate change mitigation and
adaptation goals, less well known (e.g. tax) benefits of woodland ownership, and
opportunities to gain additional income through carbon markets
Messenger People are heavily influenced by who Encourage land managers to become a ‘woodland champion’ to reinforce woodland
communicates information planting as a social norm
Personalisation Personal messages increase response rates Add hand written instructions and contact details to information packs and application
forms
Affect Use strong feelings to prompt decisions Highlight regions or business types with a high carbon footprint and emphasise the
negative environmental effects (while highlighting the opportunities offered by
woodland creation)
Incentive design People focus on short-term rewards Restructure incentives for woodland planting so they are ‘front-loaded’ and fit well with
helping to meet other management objectives, e.g. improving adjacent habitat
SOCIAL Social norms Tell people what others are doing so that Highlight the ‘pro-social’ behaviour of land manager's neighbours and peers who plant
people are made explicitly aware of other woodland
people's good behaviour
Networks Using social networks to encourage Encourage collective interest in woodland planting (e.g. by increasing grant rates once a
collective behaviour threshold level of woodland creation has been achieved in a locality)
Commitment Public commitment makes action more likely Encourage public commitments to create woodlands (and then publish pledges on websites)
Exemplify Individuals often respond to reciprocity Encourage woodland creation through example and by public commitments
and fairness
TIMELY Priming People are influenced by subconscious cues Prime target audiences with woodland creation success stories and demonstration sites
Framing and mental People assign decisions to different mental Promote options that allow people to assign woodland creation to different mental
accounts accounts accounts (e.g. as a retirement fund, or source of non-market benefits)
Key moments Timing interventions at critical points Introduce interventions following media coverage of climate change or flood events or at
key life stages when and managers are open to change (e.g. retirement from active
farming, or new ownership)

*Table 3 provides a summary types of nudges falling under each of the EAST categories.

extent to which financial returns by themselves explain overall reconversion of woodland back to agriculture is not allowed, focusing
woodland cover in the long-run remains an important question, on encouraging initial woodland creation and subsequent management
but one only empirical analysis is likely to resolve (and only where will be most important. Elsewhere, nudges aimed at encouraging long-
the requisite financial data are available). term retention of land under forestry may also be very important. In
The long-term nature of woodland creation may imply that deci- such countries long-term monitoring of land use change could help
sions depend more upon the ‘reflective system’ (i.e. deliberate and identify the extent to which nudges or related policies result in a perma-
self-conscious thinking) than the ‘automatic system’ (i.e. rapid and in- nent switch to woodlands.
stinctive modes) of cognitive processing (cf. Thaler and Sunstein, By themselves, nudges cannot be expected invariably to provide a
2008). If so, nudges that target the latter might be expected to have little solution. For land managers struggling with their short-term cash-
influence. However, which nudges are most effective is a question that flow to make a profit, for example, many nudges may be ineffective un-
requires empirical evidence to answer. Nudges that target the reflective less also accompanied by enhanced financial incentives. While nudges
system might prove the most effective, but the extent to which this can operate outside of incentives and regulation, they sometimes
holds (if at all) can only be known with certainty after trialling different work best in concert with them. Recent case-study research has con-
nudges. firmed that multifaceted forestry interventions can be particularly effec-
tive at promoting sustainability behaviours including woodland
5.2. Practical considerations creation (O’Brien et al., in press).
Their success in other contexts points to a need to investigate whether
Nudges may be most effective if tailored to specific groups to take ac- nudges would provide a cost-effective mechanism to encourage wood-
count of differences in land managers' mindsets, motivations, circum- land creation. Pilot studies such as RCTs will be needed to address this.
stances and behaviour – such as whether they have previously created Given lack of certainty concerning the extent to which nudges will
woodlands. For example, as preferences for analytical or intuitive think- prove effective, adopting a ‘test, learn, adapt’ approach – along the lines
ing vary, nudges targeted at choices that rely upon analytical thinking recommended by BIT (Haynes et al., 2012), may provide the most useful
(Sunstein, 2014; Hagman et al., 2015) may be most effective for some basis for investigating which work, or do not work, in particular contexts.
individuals. Similarly, the most effective nudges for those land man- This would also provide a basis for determining to what extent differenti-
agers for whom financial considerations are the main priority may be ating nudges or targeting specific groups is cost-effective.
nudges which focus upon the private benefits of woodland creation Nudges may need to be applied in a series of steps – a combination
(e.g. highlighting less well known financial advantages of creating (or sequence) of passive nudges, say to increase general awareness,
woodlands), whereas the most effective those for whom ethical issues followed by nudges that encourage more active decision-making. Evi-
related to, for example, climate change are the major concern, may be dence from pilot studies could help in identifying the extent to which
nudges focusing upon societal and community benefits. Land manager changes at particular intervention points or in specific elements (e.g. the
typologies and segmentations (e.g. Eves et al., 2014) may prove useful commitment to plant woodland) leads to subsequent woodland creation.
inputs in tailoring nudges. Pilot studies could also provide a basis for comparing the relative efficacy
The most effective nudges at increasing woodland cover may differ of different nudges in encouraging woodland creation, as well as compar-
between countries. In countries such as the UK, for example, where isons of their cost-effectiveness compared to other instruments (e.g.

Please cite this article as: Valatin, G., et al., Insights from behavioural economics for forest economics and environmental policy: Potential nudges
to encourage woodland creation..., Forest Policy and Economics (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2016.06.012
8 G. Valatin et al. / Forest Policy and Economics xxx (2016) xxx–xxx

financial incentives). Gathering further qualitative evidence, including on that allows for the social endogeneity of preferences and for optimization
any existing informal uses of nudges in forestry, would also prove or some other protocol to be used in selecting policy options remains a
insightful. fundamental challenge. In the interim, for policy appraisal, pragmatic ap-
Given the long-term nature of woodland creation, trialling nudge- proaches – such as adopting target-consistent values based upon the cost
related policies such as ‘ask’ and ‘think’ that more fully engage the ‘reflec- of achieving them – such as currently used in the UK for social values of
tive system’ of cognitive processing could prove very useful too. Applica- carbon (for discussion, see Valatin (2014)), and tools such as sensitivity
tions such as encouraging reduced water use under the WaterSmart analysis will continue to prove useful.
programme in Australia (Ampt and Ashton-Graham, 2013) suggests While recognising that policy nudges are not a panacea (Selinger
such approaches can be effective, although little evidence exists in the lit- and Whyte, 2012) and will often need to be applied in conjunction
erature on their cost-effectiveness at present. with other measures, investigating their potential in addressing climate
change mitigation and adaptation, as well as other agendas, will be
5.3. Ethical considerations important in developing cost-effective policies in forestry and other sec-
tors. Given current interest in Great Britain within the Forestry Commis-
The normative aspects of nudges have received a great deal of criti- sion, results from applications of nudges to UK forestry may also be
cal attention in the literature, with consideration to, amongst other anticipated before long.
things, their liberal credentials (Grüne-Yanoff, 2012), transparency of
implementation (Bovens, 2008), and paternalism (Hausman and Acknowledgements
Welch, 2010). These appraisals have led some, although not all (e.g.
Nagatsu, 2015), to conclude that nudges can constitute an infringement Thanks to Jianhua Zhou, Pradeep Kumar, and participants at the
of personal autonomy and are intrinsically manipulative. Indeed, objec- NFFE 2015 conference, as well as to Chris Quine and Helen Mackay for
tions to the use of nudges often focus on the idea that they are intrusive, their comments and suggestions. Thanks also to Shashi Kant and to
and it is useful to acknowledge that there will always be some actors the local conference organisers and hosts, including Jintao Hu, Lijun
who object to any governmental interference (explicit or otherwise) Liu, Yuanyuan Yi and the managers of the Inner Mongolia Da-Xing-
with decisions about private property. However, some argue that An-Ling State Forest. Darren Moseley undertook initial literature re-
there is no neutral architecture (Johnson et al., 2012) and it is views on which this paper builds and was responsible for drafting
recognised that ‘all government policies include, to a greater or lesser much of the sections on existing evidence and potential application of
extent, some element of intended behaviour change’ (House of Lords, nudges, and is considered joint lead-author. Norman Dandy was re-
2011), and ethical issues relating to nudges can be addressed in a num- sponsible for drafting text on barriers to woodland creation and applica-
ber of ways. These include ensuring adequate oversight through public tion of the SoC model to the application of nudges.
consultation and permission, transparency and monitoring of public
concerns, avoiding conflicts of interest and ensuring claims made are
true (Halpern, 2015). Ensuring claims are not misleading or biased References
can be especially important in designing nudges, the information con- Allcott, H., 2011. Social norms and energy conservation. J. Public Econ. 95, 1082–1095.
tent of which, could otherwise risk just being viewed as a form of http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2011.03.003.
propaganda. Ampt, L., Ashton-Graham, C., 2013. Ask Is the New Nudge and ‘Choice’ Causes ‘Spill over’
— Lessons from Effective Behaviour Change Programs in Australian Cities. Envecon
Would the use of ‘nudges’ for woodland creation raise normative con- Conference, London (www.eftec.co.uk/docman/envecon-2013/boyd-presentation/
cerns as have been levelled in other contexts? While the intent behind download).
some of the proposed mechanisms (such as default registration of Atkinson, G., Bateman, I.J., Mourato, S., 2012. Recent advances in the valuation of ecosys-
tem services and biodiversity. Oxf. Rev. Econ. Policy 28, 22–47. http://dx.doi.org/10.
whole land holdings) may appear less than wholly transparent, it is un- 1093/oxrep/grs007.
likely that any pose a significant threat to agents' core preference struc- Ayres, I., Raseman, S., Shih, A., 2009. Evidence from Two Large Field Experiments that Peer
ture. Thus, following Nagatsu's (2015) argument, it is perhaps unlikely Comparison Feedback can Reduce Residential Energy Usage. NBER Working Paper
15386. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA http://dx.doi.org/10.
that the nudges will constitute infringements of the personal autonomy
2139/ssrn.1434950.
of land managers. Tailoring nudges to account for the intrinsic variation Barrera-Osorio, F., Bertrand, M., Linden, L.L., Perez-Calle, F., 2011. Improving the design of
of beliefs and attitudes amongst land managers could reduce this threat conditional transfer programs: evidence from a randomized education experiment in
Colombia. Am. Econ. J. Appl. Econ 3, 167–195. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/app.3.2.167.
further and help avoid potential perverse (‘reactance’) effects (Ampt
Beatty, T.K.M., Blow, L., Crossley, T.F., O'Dea, C., 2011. Cash by any Other Name? Evi-
and Ashton-Graham, 2013) associated with a mismatch of values. dence on Labelling from the UK Winter Fuel Payment. IFS Working Paper 11/10.
Nonetheless, recognising ethics to be culturally-specific, trialling Institute for Fiscal Studies, London, UK http://www.ifs.org.uk/wps/wp1110.pdf).
nudges may not be considered ethically acceptable in certain countries, Bell, M., 1999. A Survey of 50 Farmers in Lancashire to Determine their Attitude to Wood-
land Planting and Management. Countryside Commission, Forestry Commission, Lan-
or not without more formal democratic oversight. For example, the Ger- cashire County Council, Environment Directorate, Agri-Business Services.
man Constitution could be interpreted as explicitly prohibiting experi- Bettinger, E.P., Long, B.T., Oreopoulos, P., Sanbonmatsu, L., 2012. The role of application as-
ments with nudges without Parliamentary clearance (Halpern, 2015). sistance and information in college decisions: results from the h&r block fafsa exper-
iment. Q. J. Econ. 127, 1205–1242. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjs017.
BIT, 2010a. Behavioural Insights Team Annual Update 2010–11. Cabinet Office Behavioural
5.4. Other potential forestry applications Insights Team (30 pp.) Cabinet Office, London, UK https://www.gov.uk/government/
uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/60537/Behaviour-Change-Insight-
Team-Annual-Update_acc.pdf.
Although their potential use in encouraging woodland creation is BIT, 2010b. Applying Behavioural Insight to Health (30 pp.) Cabinet Office Behavioural In-
the primary focus of the case study in this paper, the applicability of sights Team, London, UK https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/
nudges could usefully be explored in a range of other forest policy attachment_data/file/60524/403936_BehaviouralInsight_acc.pdf.
BIT, 2011. Behaviour Change and Energy Use. Cabinet Office Behavioural Insights Team,
areas too. These include use in encouraging diversification of London, UK (34 pp.) https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/
existing forests to reduce risks of pests and disease outbreaks, as attachment_data/file/60536/behaviour-change-and-energy-use.pdf.
well as in mobilising wood/fibre for new markets such as woodfuel. BIT, 2012. Applying Behavioural Insights to Reduce Fraud, Error and Debt. Cabinet Office
Behavioural Insights Team, London, UK (38 pp.) https://www.gov.uk/government/
uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/60539/BIT_FraudErrorDebt_
6. Concluding remarks accessible.pdf.
Bovens, L., 2008. The Ethics of Nudge. In: Grüne-Yanoff, T., Hansson, S.O. (Eds.), Preference
Insights from behavioural economics provide a rich seam of evidence Change: Approaches from Philosophy, Economics and Psychology. Springer, Berlin,
pp. 207–219 http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-90-481-2593-7_10.
that could usefully be mined in developing forest (and environmental) Breffle, W.S., Rowe, R.D., 2002. Comparing choice question formats for evaluating natural
economics and policy. Developing a consistent valuation framework resource tradeoffs. Land Econ. 78, 298–314. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/3147275.

Please cite this article as: Valatin, G., et al., Insights from behavioural economics for forest economics and environmental policy: Potential nudges
to encourage woodland creation..., Forest Policy and Economics (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2016.06.012
G. Valatin et al. / Forest Policy and Economics xxx (2016) xxx–xxx 9

Bromley, D., 2008. Volitional pragmatism. Ecol. Econ. 68, 1–13. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/ Jacobsen, J.B., Boiesen, J.H., Thorsen, B.J., Strange, N., 2008. What's in a name? The use of
j.ecolecon.2008.08.012. quantitative measures versus “iconised” species when valuing biodiversity. Environ.
Burton, R., 2004. Seeing through the “good farmer's” eyes: towards developing an under- Resour. Econ. 39, 247–263. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10640-007-9107-6.
standing of the social symbolic value of “productivist” behaviour. Sociol. Rural. 44, Jang, S., Hart, P., 2015. Polarized frames on “climate change” and “global warming” across
195–215. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9523.2004.00270.x. countries and states: evidence from twitter big data. Glob. Environ. Chang. 32, 11–17.
Burton, R., Wilson, O., 2000. Farmers' Resistance to Woodland Planting in Community For- John, P., Smith, G., Stoker, G., 2009. Nudge nudge, think think: two strategies for changing
ests: The Influence of Social and Cultural Factors. De Montfort University, Leicester. civic behaviour. Polit. Q. 80, 361–370. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-923X.2009.
Canadell, J.G., Raupach, M.R., 2008. Managing forests for climate change mitigation. Sci- 02001.x.
ence 320, 1456–1457. http://dx.doi.org/10.1126/science.1155458. Johnson, E.J., Goldstein, D., 2003. Do defaults save lives? Science 302, 1338–1339. http://
Christie, M., Hanley, N., Warren, J., Murphy, K., Wright, R., Hyde, T., 2006. Valuing the di- dx.doi.org/10.1126/science.1091721.
versity of biodiversity. Ecol. Econ. 58, 304–317. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon. Johnson, E.J., Shu, S.B., Dellaert, B.G.C., Fox, C., Goldstein, D.G., Häubl, G., Larrick, R.P.,
2005.07.034. Payne, J.W., Peters, E., Schkade, D., Wansink, B., Weber, E.U., 2012. Beyond nudges:
Corbett, J.B., 2015. Media power and climate change. Nat. Clim. Chang. 5, 288–290. http:// Tools of a choice architecture. Mark. Lett. 23 (2), 487–504.
dx.doi.org/10.1038/nclimate2592. Kant, S., 2003. Extending the boundaries of forest economics. Forest Policy Econ. 5, 39–56.
Costanza, R., 2004. Value Theory and Energy. In: Cleveland, C. (Ed.), Encyclopedia of Ener- http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S1389-9341(02)00045-X.
gy Vol. 6. Elsevier Science, Amsterdam, pp. 337–346. Kant, S., Wang, S., Deegen, P., Hostettler, M., von Detten, R., Howard, T., Laband, D.,
Czajkowski, M., Hanley, N., 2009. Using labels to investigate scope effects in stated prefer- Montgomery, C., Robert, N., Sekot, W., Valatin, G., Zhang, D., 2013. New frontiers of forest
ence methods. Environ. Resour. Econ. 44, 521–535. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/ economics. Forest Policy Econ. 35, 1–8. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2013.06.002.
s10640-009-9299-z. Kant, S., Vertinski, I., Zheng, B., 2016. Valuation of First Nations peoples' social, cultural,
Dandy, N., 2012. Understanding Land-Manager Decision Making: A Framework for For- and land use activities using life satisfaction approach. Forest Policy Econ. (in this
estry. Forest Research, Farnham. issue).
DECC, 2014. LEAF Evaluation. Department of Energy & Climate Change, London, UK. Kaplowitz, M.D., Hoehn, J.P., 2001. Do focus groups and individual interviews reveal the
DeShazo, J.R., Fermo, G., 2002. Designing choice sets for stated preference methods: the same information for natural resource valuation? Ecol. Econ. 36, 237–247.
effects of complexity on choice consistency. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 44, 123–143. Kinzig, A.P., Ehrlich, P.R., Alston, L.J., Arrow, K., Barrett, S., Timothy, G., Daily, G.C., Levin, B.,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1006/jeem.2001.1199. Levin, S., Oppenheimer, M., Ostrom, E., 2013. Social norms and global environmental
Dolan, P., Hallsworth, M., Halpern, D., King, D., Metcalfe, R., Vlaev, I., 2012. Influencing be- challenges: the complex interaction of behaviors, values, and policy. Bioscience 63,
haviour: the mindspace way. J. Econ. Psychol. 33, 264–277. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/ 164–175. http://dx.doi.org/10.1525/bio.2013.63.3.5.
j.joep.2011.10.009. Knetsch, J.L., 2005. Behavioral Economics and Sustainable Forest Management. In: Kant, S.,
Duesberg, S., O'Connor, D., Dhubháin, Á.N., 2013. To plant or not to plant-Irish farmers' Berry, R.A. (Eds.), Economics, Sustainability, and Natural Resources: Economics of
goals and values with regard to afforestation. Land Use Policy 32, 155–164. http:// Sustainable Forest Management. Springer, Dordrecht, The Netherlands, pp. 91–103
dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2012.10.021. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/1-4020-3518-7_5.
Dziegielewska, D.A., Mendelsohn, R., 2007. Does “no” mean “no”? A protest methodology. Kumar, P., Kant, S., 2016. Revealed social preferences and Joint Forest Management out-
Environ. Resour. Econ. 38, 71–87. comes. Forest Policy Econ. (in this issue).
Entman, R., 1993. Framing: toward clarification of a fractured paradigm. J. Commun. 43, Laband, D., 2013. The neglected stepchildren of forest-based ecosystem services: cultural,
51–58. spiritual, and aesthetic values. Forest Policy Econ.
Evans, J.S.B.T., Stanovich, K.E., 2013. Dual-process theories of higher cognition: ad- Lawrence, A., Dandy, N., 2014. Private landowners' approaches to planting and managing
vancing the debate. Perspect. Psychol. Sci. 8, 223–241. http://dx.doi.org/10. forests in the UK: What's the evidence? Land Use Policy 351–360.
1177/1745691612460685. Lawrence, A., Marzano, M., 2014. Is the private forest sector adapting to climate change? A
Eves, C., Johnson, M., Smith, S., Quick, T., Langley, E., Jenner, M., Richardson, W., Glynn, M., study of forest managers in north Wales. Ann. For. Sci.
Anable, J., Crabtree, B., White, C., Black, J., MacDonald, C., Slee, B., 2014. Analysis of the Levine, J., Chan, K.M.A., Satterfield, T., 2015. From rational actor to efficient complexity
Potential Effects of Various Influences and Interventions on Woodland Management manager: Exorcising the ghost of Homo economicus with a unified synthesis of cog-
and Creation Decisions , Using a Segmentation Model to Categorise Sub-Groups. nition research. Ecol. Econ. 114, 22–32. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2015.03.
Defra, London. 010.
FAO, 2015. Global Forest Resources Assessment 2015. Desk Reference, United Nations Lobley, M., Winter, H., Millard, N., Butler, A., Winter, M., 2012. Making Land Available
Food and Agricultural Organisation, Rome. for Woodland Creation. CRPR Research Report 35, Centre for Rural Policy Research.
FC, 2015. Forestry Statistics 2015. Forestry Commission, Edinburgh. University of, Exeter, http://www.forestry.gov.uk/pdf/Exeterreport.pdf/$FILE/
Flachaire, E., Hollard, G., 2006. Controlling starting-point bias in double-bounded contingent Exeterreport.pdf.
valuation surveys. Land Econ. 82, 103–111. http://dx.doi.org/10.3368/le.82.1.103. Macmillan, D.C., Philip, L., Hanley, N., Alvarez-Farizo, B., 2002. Valuing the non-market
Fryer, R.G., 2011. Financial incentives and student achievement: evidence from random- benefits of wild goose conservation: a comparison of interview and group based ap-
ized trials. Q. J. Econ. 126, 1755–1798. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjr045. proaches. Ecol. Econ. 43, 49–59. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0921-8009(02)00182-9.
Fryer, R.G., Levitt, S.D., Sado, S., 2012. Enhancing the Efficacy of Teacher Incentives Madrian, B.C., Shea, D.F., 2001. The power of suggestion: inertia in 401(k) participation
through Loss Aversion: A Field Experiment. NBER Working Paper 18237. National Bu- and savings behavior. Q. J. Econ. 116, 1149–1187. http://dx.doi.org/10.1162/
reau of Economic Research, Cambridge MA http://www.nber.org/papers/w18237. 003355301753265543.
Glynn, M., Richardson, W., Anable, J., Quick, T., Rowcroft, P., Smith, S., 2012. Independent Matthies, B.D., Kalliokoski, T., Eyvindson, K., Honkela, N., Hukkinen, J.I., Kuusinen, N.J.,
Panel on Forestry Woodland Owner Survey. Final Report to the Independent Panel on Räisänen, P., Valsta, L.T., 2016. Nudging service providers and assessing service
Forestry. URS, London. trade-offs to reduce the social inefficiencies of payments for ecosystem services
Gowdy, J., 2004. The revolution in welfare economics and its implications for environmen- schemes. Environ. Sci. Pol. 55, 228–237.
tal valuation and policy. Land Econ. 80, 239–257. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/3654741. Milon, J.W., Scrogin, D., 2006. Latent preferences and valuation of wetland ecosystem
Grist, M., 2010. Steer. Mastering our Behaviour through Instinct, Environment and Rea- restoration. Ecol. Econ. 56, 162–175. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2005.
son. RSA, London, UK https://www.thersa.org/discover/publications-and-articles/ 01.009.
reports/steer-the-report. Moseley, D., Valatin, G., 2013. Insights from Behavioural Economics for Ecosystem Ser-
Groeneveld, R.A., 2010. Framing and training to induce preference learning in choice ex- vices Valuation and Sustainability. Research Report. Forestry Commission, Edinburgh.
periments. Mar. Resour. Econ. 25, 233–245. Moseley, D., Dandy, N., Edwards, D., Valatin, G., 2014. Behavioural Policy ‘Nudges’ to En-
Grüne-Yanoff, T., 2012. Old wine in new casks: Libertarian paternalism still violates liberal courage Woodland Creation for Climate Change Mitigation. Research Report. Forestry
principles. Soc. Choice Welf. 38 (4), 635–645. Commission, Edinburgh.
Hagman, W., Andersson, D., Vasfjall, D., Tinghog, G., 2015. Public views on policies involv- Nagatsu, M., 2015. Social nudges: their mechanisms and justification. Rev. Philos. Psychol.
ing nudges. Rev. Philos. Psychol. 6 (3), 439–453. 24, 1–17. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s13164-015-0245-4.
Halpern, D., 2013. Applying Behavioural Insights. Glasgow, 29th May 2013. Presentation. Neumann, P., Krogman, N., 2007. “My Grandfather Would Roll Over in his Grave”: Family
http://www.gov.scot/Resource/0042/00424278.pdf. Farming and Tree Plantations on Farmland. Rural Sociol. 72 (1), 111–135. http://dx.
Halpern, D., 2015. Inside the Nudge Unit. Penguin, London. doi.org/10.1526/003601107781147428.
Hausman, D.M., Welch, B., 2010. Debate: to nudge or not to nudge. J Polit Philos 18, Nisbet, M., 2009. Communicating climate change: why frames matter for public engage-
123–136. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9760.2009.00351.x. ment. Environ. Sci. Pol. Sustain. 51 (2), 514–518. http://dx.doi.org/10.3200/ENVT.51.
Haynes, L., Service, O., Goldacre, B., Torgerson, D., 2012. Test, Learn, Adapt: Randomised 2.12-23.
Controlled Trials. Policy Paper Published by the Cabinet Office Behavioural Insights Nisbet, T., Roe, P., Marrington, S., Thomas, H., Broadmeadow, S., Valatin, G., 2015. Slowing
Team (available at www.cabinetoffice.gov.uk.). the Flow at Pickering, Final Report to Defra of FCERM Multi-Objective Flood Manage-
Henderson, K., Anand, M., Bauch, C., 2013. Carrot or stick? Modelling how landowner be- ment Demonstration Project RMP5455: Phase II. Forest Research, Farnham.
havioural responses can cause incentive-based forest governance to backfire. PLoS Nudge blog, 2008. How the Febreze Marketing Campaign Reduced Disease in Ghana
One 8, e77735. http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0077735. [WWW Document]. (URL) http://nudges.wordpress.com/how-the-febreze-
Hilborn, R.C., 2004. Sea gulls, butterflies, and grasshoppers: a brief history of the butterfly marketing-campaign-improved-public-health-in-ghana/.
effect in nonlinear dynamics. Am. J. Phys. 72, 425–427. http://dx.doi.org/10.1119/1. iNudgeYou, 2012. The Stairs to Fitness [WWW Document]. (URL http://www.inudgeyou.
1636492. com/health-nudge-the-stairs-to-fitness/).
Hoehn, J.P., Lupi, F., Kaplowitz, M.D., 2010. Stated choice experiments with complex eco- O’Brien, L., Morris, J., Marzano, M., Dandy, N., 2016. Promoting Sustainability Behaviours
system changes: the effect of information formats on estimated variances and choice Through Forestry. Forestry, http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/forestry/cpw030 (in press).
parameters. J. Agric. Resour. Econ. 35, 568–590. O'Neill, S., Williams, H.T.P., Kurz, T., Wiersma, B., Boykoff, M., 2015. Dominant frames in
House of Lords, 2011. Science and Technology Select Committee Report. Behaviour legacy and social media coverage of the IPCC fifth assessment report. Nat. Clim.
Change. The House of Lords, London, UK. Chang. 5, 380–385. http://dx.doi.org/10.1038/nclimate2535.

Please cite this article as: Valatin, G., et al., Insights from behavioural economics for forest economics and environmental policy: Potential nudges
to encourage woodland creation..., Forest Policy and Economics (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2016.06.012
10 G. Valatin et al. / Forest Policy and Economics xxx (2016) xxx–xxx

Ovaskainen, V., Kniivila, M., 2005. Consumer versus citizen preferences in contingent val- Thaler, R.R., Sunstein, C.C., 2008. Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth, and
uation: evidence on the role of question framing. Aust. J. Agric. Resour. Econ. 49, Happiness. Yale University Press, New Haven, CT.
379–394. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8489.2005.00309.x. Thomas, H.J.D., Paterson, J.S., Metzger, M.J., Sing, L., 2015. Towards a research agenda for
Pearson, L.J., Kashima, Y., Pearson, C.J., 2012. Clarifying protected and utilitarian values of crit- woodland expansion in Scotland. For. Ecol. Manag. 44. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.
ical capital. Ecol. Econ. 73, 206–210. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2011.10.027. foreco.2015.04.003.
Pouta, E., 2004. Attitude and belief questions as a source of context effect in a contingent Torres, A.B., MacMillan, D.C., Skutsch, M., Lovett, J.C., 2013. The valuation of forest carbon ser-
valuation survey. J. Econ. Psychol. 25, 229–242. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0167- vices by Mexican citizens: the case of Guadalajara city and La Primavera biosphere re-
4870(02)00170-8. serve. Reg. Environ. Chang. 13, 661–680. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10113-012-0336-z.
Prochaska, J.O., Diclemente, C.C., Norcross, J.C., 1992. In search of how people change — Umpfenbach, K., 2014. Influences on Consumer Behaviour: Policy Implications beyond
applications to addictive behaviors. Am. Psychol. 1102–1114. Nudging. European Commission (25 pp.).
Combating Climate Change — A Role for UK Forests. In: Read, D.J., Freer-Smith, P.H., UNFCCC, 2015. Paris Agreement. Conference of the Parties Twenty-First Session, United
Morison, J.I.L., Hanley, N., West, C.C., Snowdon, P. (Eds.), An Assessment of the Poten- Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, FCCC/CP/2015/L.9.
tial of the UK's Trees and Woodlands to Mitigate and Adapt to Climate Change. The Valatin, G., 2014. Carbon Valuation in Forestry and Prospects for European Harmonisation.
Stationery Office, Edinburgh. Technical Report 97. European Forestry Institute (http://www.efi.int/files/attachments/
Rinaldi, F., Jonsson, R., Sallnäs, O., Trubins, R., 2015. Behavioral modelling in a decision publications/efi_tr_97_2014_valatin.pdf).).
support system. Forests 6, 311–327. http://dx.doi.org/10.3390/f6020311. Valatin, G., 2005. Justice, Human Security and the Environment (PhD thesis) Dipartimento
Schultz, P., Nolan, J., Cialdini, R., Goldstein, N., Griskevicius, V., 2007. The constructive, de- di Economia Politica, University of Siena, Italy.
structive, and reconstructive power of social norms. Psychol. Sci. 18, 429–434. http:// Valatin, G., Price, C., 2014. How Cost-Effective Is Forestry for Climate Change Mitigation?
dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9280.2007.01917.x. In: Fenning, T. (Ed.), Challenges and Opportunities for the World's Forests in the 21st
Selinger, E., Whyte, K.P., 2012. Nudging cannot solve complex policy problems. Eur. J. Risk Century. Springer
Regul. 1, 26–31. Volpp, K.G., Troxel, A.B., Pauly, M.V., Glick, H.A., Puig, A., Asch, D.A., Galvin, R., Zhu, J., Wan,
Shahi, C., Kant, S., 2013. Are Forest User Groups Rational Economic or Social Agents? Ex- F., Deguzman, J., Corbett, E., Weiner, J., Audrain-McGovern, J., 2009. A randomized,
perimental Evidence from India. Post-Faustmann Forest Resource Economics. Spring- controlled trial of financial incentives for smoking cessation. N. Engl. J. Med. 360
er, Dordrecht, pp. 23–39. (7), 699–709.
Shogren, J., 2007. Behavior in forest economics. J. For. Econ. 12, 233–235. Watkins, C., Williams, D., Lloyd, T., 1996. Constraints on farm woodland planting in En-
Stubbs, B., 2011. Barriers to Woodland Expansion. A Discussion Paper for the Woodland gland: a study of Nottinghamshire farmers. Forestry 69, 166–176.
Expansion Advisory Group. WEAG Paper 15a. White, P.C.L., Bennett, A.C., Hayes, E.J.V., 2001. The use of willingness-to-pay approaches
Sunstein, C. (Ed.), 2000. Behavioral Law and Economics. Cambridge University Press, in mammal conservation. Mammal Rev. 31, 151–167. http://dx.doi.org/10.1046/j.
New York. 1365-2907.2001.00083.x.
Sunstein, C.R., 2014. Why Nudge? The Politics of Liberal Paternalism. Yale University
Press, New Haven.

Please cite this article as: Valatin, G., et al., Insights from behavioural economics for forest economics and environmental policy: Potential nudges
to encourage woodland creation..., Forest Policy and Economics (2016), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2016.06.012

You might also like