Money - A Short Course On Money & Banking - Hummel

You might also like

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 11

Short Course on Money and Banking

http://wfhummel.net/shortcourse.html

The Elusive Concept of Money Money can be defined as whatever is widely accepted as a medium of exchange. Of course to be accepted, it must be seen as a store of value. These basic properties, however, do not explain how something gains status as money and how it is to be measured. Keynes held that the primary concept in the theory of money is the unit of account. Throughout history, States have established what is to serve as legal tender. They have done so by (1) giving a name to the unit of account; (2) declaring what token is legal tender measured in that unit; and (3) enforcing debts and contracts payable in that token. The point is that debts and contract prices must be expressed in terms of the unit of account while the token can be whatever the government chooses, and can be changed independent of the unit of account. In the U.S. the unit of account is the dollar, and the token is a dollar bill. When the U.S. established the dollar in 1792, the token was a gold coin of specified weight. Endowing Money Tokens with Value Any State with the power to tax can establish its own currency by declaring what token is to be legal tender. All modern States have adopted intrinsically worthless tokens for their currencies, known as fiat money. The State necessarily holds a monopoly on the production of fiat money. However it must issue enough for the economy to function efficiently plus enough more to enable the public it to pay its taxes. The source of the States money tokens is normally its central bank. In the US, the tokens are carried as liabilities on the Feds balance sheet, backed by the financial assets bought from the private sector with those tokens. Those liabilities together with the deposits of private banks at the Fed comprise the monetary base, which we will refer to as base money. Base money acquires value because of its status as legal tender but more importantly because that is what the private sector must deliver in paying federal taxes. In effect base money is a tax credit. Those who have no tax liabilities will readily accept payment in base money because it is needed by

so many others. The viability of base money ultimately depends on the government widely enforcing tax collection, and acting to maintain a modest rate of price inflation. Dual Role of Banks Banks as we know them today have two distinct roles. They are profit-seeking enterprises as well as depositories. Their profit-seeking activities include a variety of services. However we will focus on their service as intermediaries who provide a link between those with savings to invest and those in need of funds. As depositories banks accept deposits, provide payment facilities, and issue cash on demand in exchange for deposits. They pay no interest on demand deposits and very modest interest on savings deposits. They also offer term deposits at higher interest rates because those deposits provide a more stable supply of funding to back their lending. We will use the term banks to mean any financial institution that serves as a depository, such as commercial banks and thrifts. That does not include the subsidiaries of banks or bank holding companies, which cannot accept deposits but are permitted to engage in a variety of investment activities and to hold assets not allowed to banks themselves. Two Kinds of Money A fractional reserve banking system has two kinds of money, base money and bank money. The Fed creates base money when it purchases Treasury securities from the public. It pays by simply crediting the seller's bank with a deposit at the Fed, while the bank credits the seller with a deposit in his own account. Base money is the definitive money of the nation, which means the government has no obligation to convert it into another form of asset. It comprises the cash held by the private sector and bank deposits at the Fed. All payments to and from the government require the transfer of base money. For example, when one writes a check to pay his taxes, his bank must surrender that much in reserves of base money to the Treasury for the check to clear. Bank money refers to deposits in banks, all of which are claims on base money. The viability of bank money depends on the promise that it can be

converted on demand into base money at par. Bank money is created when a bank issues a loan. It does so by simply crediting the borrower's account with a deposit. The bank must hold enoughreserves of base money to meet the reserve ratio requirement on its demand deposits. Bank money is the credit side of a balance sheet relation. Every dollar of credit in the form of bank money is matched by an equal amount of debt. For the borrower, a bank loan creates a credit (the deposit) and a matching debt (the obligation to repay the loan). For the bank, the loan creates an interestearning asset (the loan contract) and an equal liability (the borrowers deposit). The Private Sector Money Supply What is meant by the money supply in reference to the private sector? The term itself implies that a certain amount of money exists at any given time, even though the quantity may be unknown. In a fractional reserve system, there can be no meaningful measure of the money supply, as will be explained. The Fed has its own arbitrary measures of the money supply which it once used to help guide its monetary policy decisions. It defines the money supply as the total cash in circulation and the deposit liabilities of banks and thrifts. At one time it set targets for the growth of the money supply. Now it largely ignores its own measures because it has found little correlation between them and its major policy objectives limiting inflation and unemployment. The Fed's definition of the money supply includes only what the non-bank sector holds. Thus the reserves of banks, i.e. vault cash and deposits at the Fed, are not included in the monetary aggregates, even though they are a part of the monetary base. That means when a bank makes payments to the public, it increases the money supply. When it receives payments from the public such as interest on loans, the money supply decreases. An important shortcoming of the Fed's definition is that it ignores bank lines of credit which can be exercised at the discretion of the borrower. Firms often hold substantial lines of credit at their banks, which they can use on short notice. Likewise consumers hold lines of credit in their credit card accounts that are just as useful for purchases as checking accounts or the currency in their wallets. Lines of credit increase liquidity, which is ultimately what counts in terms of effective aggregate demand.

When someone uses a credit card in a purchase, he automatically expands the money supply. The seller receives a new deposit in his account, which increases the total of demand deposits in the banking system until the buyer pays off the loan. Consumers who roll over their credit card loans rather than paying them off have increased the money supply on their own initiative by hundreds of billions of dollars. Thus the effective money supply is substantially larger and less measurable than the Fed's definition. Banks and Base Money A private enterprise with sufficient financial capital may obtain a charter that permits it to accept deposits of base money from the public, and to issue loans in the form of bank money. When one deposits a check or cash in his account at a bank, he receives credit in exchange, namely bank money. We expect banks to redeem those credits for cash on demand and to honor checks written against those credits. Most of the money in use today by the private sector exists as credits issued by private banks. When one pays by writing a check on his bank deposit, if the payee deposits the check in another bank, the payer's bank must transfer an equal amount of reserves to the payee's bank. Thus base money is the foundation of the bank money system. Base Money as Credit In reality, base money itself is a form of credit. In the same way a contract can be viewed either as a document or the agreement it represents, money can be viewed either as a token or the credit it represents. Since credit for the holder is debt for the issuer, money can also be viewed as a token representing third party debt. In the case of base money, the third party is the Fed. All base money originates with the Fed. For the most part, it is issued in exchange for securities the public bought from the Treasury with base money previously acquired from the Fed. This circular system of credit is difficult for some to understand, especially for those who think of money only in terms of the token itself rather than the credit represented by the token. If base money is simply a form of credit backed by Treasury securities, which are another form of credit, then what assures the viability of base money, and what is the real basis of its value? The Fed's base money liabilities are backed by its assets in the form of Treasury securities which it previously bought from

the public. But what prevents the real value of those Treasury securities from being diluted by deficit spending? As will be explained, the purchasing power of base money has very little to do with the amount of deficit spending. However it does depend in the long run on the cost to banks of acquiring base money, which the Fed itself controls. The Feds Role Since base money is a monopoly of the State, the Fed must issue enough to avoid a shortage of what the public must use to pay its taxes. In practical terms, that means it must provide whatever reserves the banking system needs to ensure the liquidity of the payment system. When the Fed needs to increase aggregate reserves, it buys Treasury securities from the public and credits the sellers' banks with additional deposits at the Fed. Conversely the Fed sells Treasury securities to the public from its own portfolio when it needs to decrease aggregate bank reserves. Bank reserves are only a small part of the monetary base, but they play a key role because they are the grease that enables the bank credit system to function. These transactions by the Fed are designed to balance supply and demand for bank reserves at the Fed's target interest rate on overnight loans between banks, otherwise known as the Fed funds rate. The Fed funds rate is the benchmark for all short-term interest rates. It has a significant influence on the amount of bank money issued, and thus the liquidity of the private sector. In controlling the Fed funds rate, the Fed necessarily relinquishes control of the amount of base money it issues. The private sector itself determines the net amount issued. Treasury Operations The Treasury spends out of its account at the Fed. It continually replenishes that account with transfers from its accounts in commercial banks where it deposits its receipts from taxes and the sale of bonds. These socalledTreasury Tax and Loan accounts in commercial banks are backed by deposits at the Fed, which are reserves of the banking system. Treasury operations simply recycle base money previously issued by the Fed. The Treasury approximately balances its receipts from taxes and the sale of bonds against its spending in order to avoid large variations in the demand deposits of the private sector which could significantly affect liquidity. It targets a fixed balance in its account at the Fed in order to minimize variations in the aggregate reserves of the banking system. The Fed compensates for the

variations by adding or draining reserves on a short-term basis through its open market operations. If the private sector holds more base money than it needs, it will normally use the excess to purchase interest-earning Treasury securities, since base money earns no interest. The Treasury will always be able to recapture its deficit spending through the sale of securities, since it can pay whatever interest rate the market demands. Managing Inflationary Expectations The interest rate the Treasury must pay to borrow is a market rate which is influenced by Fed policy. The short-term rate closely tracks the Fed funds rate due to arbitrage. Longer-term rates include a premium over the Fed funds rate which varies with inflationary expectations. Although many diverse factors affect those expectations, the Fed itself has considerable influence through its monetary policy decisions. It is therefore up to the Fed to keep inflationary expectations within acceptable limits. By doing that well, it protects the purchasing power of base money, and ensures that interest rates on long term borrowing will not become so burdensome as to hinder economic growth. The historical record shows no significant correlation between the amount of deficit spending and the inflation rate or interest rates. Most central banks now target a small positive inflation rate to provide a margin against a deflation trap. Deflation hurts aggregate demand by creating a money-hoarding psychology which is difficult to overcome, and may result in a prolonged recession. Under the gold-based system, the State's ability to counter inflationary and deflationary pressures was very limited. The Evolution of Fractional Reserve Banking London goldsmiths, originally operating as money changers, accepted coins and other gold objects for safekeeping for a fee, and issued receipts to the depositors. This has become known as warehouse banking. By the mid 17thcentury, people found it more convenient to exchange the receipts rather than the coins when making payments among themselves. This facilitated trade within the economy, and the receipts themselves gradually became the accepted form of money. The goldsmiths found that people would rarely redeem the deposited gold for their receipts. Consequently they began issuing new receipts through lending, thereby creating receipts unbacked by gold deposits. Thus began the transition from warehouse banking to fractional reserve banking in England.

Unbacked receipts were the origin of the later banknote, a promissory note issued by a bank and payable in gold coin to the bearer on demand. Fractional reserve banking was an attractive means of expanding the money supply. However occasional over-lending by bankers created problems. When their promissory notes could not be fully honored, bank runs usually followed which sometimes resulted in serious consequences for the local economy. A key difference in a modern fiat money system is the existence of the central bank. One of its roles is to act as lender of last resort. As the source of base money, it can lend whatever a bank needs to cover depositor withdrawals. If a bank is solvent but has a liquidity problem, it can borrow the funds it needs from the central bank. The Role of Bank Reserves The bulk of all money transactions today involve the transfer of bank deposits. A bank must hold reserves of base money in order to meet its depositors' cash withdrawals and to cover the checks written against their accounts. Reserves comprise a bank's vault cash and what it holds on deposit at the Fed, i.e. Fed funds. When a depositor writes a check against his account, his bank must surrender that amount in reserves to the payees bank for the check to clear. Reserves are constantly moving from one bank to another as checks are written and cleared. At the end of the day, some banks will be short of reserves and others long. Banks redistribute reserves among themselves by trading in the Fed funds market. Those long on reserves will normally lend to those short. The interest rate on interbank loans, known as the Fed funds rate, varies with supply and demand. The reserve requirement applies only to the bank's demand deposits, not its term or savings deposits. Thus when a bank depositor converts funds in a demand deposit into a term or savings deposit, he frees up the bank's reserves that were held against the demand deposit. The bank can then use those reserves in several ways. For example, it can hold them to back further lending, buy interest-earning Treasury securities, or lend them to other banks in the Fed funds market. The Fed funds rate effectively sets the upper limit on the cost of reserves to banks, and thereby determines the interest rate that banks must charge the public for loans. The interest rate influences the demand for bank loans, and

thus the net amount of bank money. Liquidity is an important factor in aggregate demand and inflationary pressure, which is why the Fed targets the Fed funds rate as its key monetary policy tool. Reserve Requirements All depository institutions -- commercial banks and thrifts -- in the United States are subject to reserve requirements on customer deposits. The required reserve ratio depends on the amount of checkable deposits a bank holds. As of year end 2009, no reserves were required on the first $10.7 million. Between $10.7 million and $55.2 million, deposits are subject to a 3% reserve. Above $55.2 million they are subject to a 10% reserve. These breakpoints are adjusted annually in accordance with money supply growth. No reserves are required against time deposits or savings accounts. Reserves are figured as the average held over a 14-day period, ending every second Wednesday. On any single day, a bank needs only enough to cover its customer's withdrawals. A bank may hold its reserves in any combination of vault cash and deposits at the Fed. As profit-seeking enterprises, banks try to keep their reserves close to the required minimum, since they earn no interest. How Banks Meet Reserve Requirements A bank loses reserves whenever it pays out cash or transfers funds by wire for its customers. Customer checks to pay out of town bills funnel back through the Fed and are charged against its reserves. A bank may also lose reserves when it advances loans or buys securities. Conversely a bank gains reserves when it receives new deposits. A bank facing a reserve deficiency has several options. It can try to borrow reserves for one or more days from another bank; sell marketable assets, such as government securities; bid for funds in the money market, such as large CDs or Eurodollars; or it can pledge collateral and borrow at the Feds discount window at a penalty rate. An active market in reserves acts to redistribute reserves to those banks that need them. However banks cannot create reserves themselves. If the aggregate demand exceeds the existing supply of reserves, the banking system as a whole has no alternative but to borrow reserves from the Fed. Factors Affecting Aggregate Reserves

There are many factors outside of the Feds control that influence the level of non-borrowed reserves. They include changes in currency holdings of the public, changes in the Treasurys cash balances at the Fed, checking system float, and foreign central bank transactions. The Fed actively compensates for these variations by adding or draining system reserves as needed to avoid large fluctuations in their market price, i.e. the Fed funds rate. The growing demand for currency is the largest single factor requiring reserve injections. The Treasury holds working balances at the Fed for making payments on behalf of the government. Drawing down those balances increases aggregate banking system reserves since it results in a transfer of base money to the banking system. In order to minimize variations in total banking system reserves due to its own spending, the Treasury targets a fixed balance of $6 billion at the Fed by transferring funds as required from its Treasury Tax & Loan accounts at commercial banks. TT&L accounts serve as collection points for receipts from taxes and the sale of securities, and are reserves of the banking system. Many foreign central banks keep working balances at the Fed to execute their dollar-denominated transactions. Drawing down of those balances increases the reserves of depository institutions receiving payments. Transfers can sometimes result in significant increases or decreases in reserves, requiring offsetting open market operations by the Fed. Bank Liquidity One of the main challenges to a bank is ensuring its own liquidity under all reasonable conditions. Liquidity for a bank means the ability to meet its financial obligations as they come due. Commercial banks differ widely in how they manage liquidity. A small bank derives its funds primarily from customer deposits, normally a fairly stable source in the aggregate. Its assets are mostly loans to small firms and households, and it usually has more deposits than it can find creditworthy borrowers for. Excess funds are typically invested in assets that will provide it with liquidity such as Fed funds loaned and U.S. government securities. The holding of assets that can readily be turned into cash when needed, is known as asset management banking. Large banks generally lack sufficient deposits to fund their main business -dealing with large companies, governments, other financial institutions, and wealthy individuals. Most borrow the funds they need from other major lenders in the form of short-term liabilities which must be continually rolled over. This is known as liability management, a much riskier method than asset

management. A small bank will lose potential income if gets its asset management wrong. A large bank that gets its liability management wrong may fail. The key to liability management is always being able to borrow. Therefore a bank's most vital asset is its creditworthiness. If there is any doubt about its credit, lenders can easily switch to another bank. The rate a bank must pay to borrow will go up rapidly with the slightest indication of trouble. If there is serious doubt, it will be unable to borrow at any rate, and will go under. In recent years, large banks have been making increasing use of asset management in order to enhance liquidity, holding a larger part of their assets as securities as well as securitizing their loans to recycle borrowed funds. A bank run is an overwhelming demand for cash by a bank's depositors. With the advent of deposit insurance, bank runs by small depositors are largely a thing of the past. Insurance is currently limited to $250,000 per deposit, which provides complete coverage to about 99% of all depositors. But it covers only about three-fourths of the total amount of deposits because many accounts far exceed the insurance limits. A large depositor assumes a risk and needs to know something about the bank's own balance sheet. However a healthy balance sheet does not eliminate all risk. Even if the depositor knows the bank has adequate liquidity, others may not. Large depositors must therefore be concerned about what others are likely to believe. A rumor about a bank, even though unfounded, can trigger a run that causes a solvent bank to fail. The Effects of Government Spending The Fed acts as a depository for the Treasury as well as member banks. All government spending is paid out of the Treasury's account at the Fed. Whenever the government spends, the Fed debits the Treasury's account and credits the Fed account of the payees bank. The Treasury attempts to minimize disturbances to aggregate banking system reserves by maintaining a nearly constant balance in its Fed account. It replenishes its Fed account with transfers from its commercial bank accounts where it deposits the receipts from taxes and the sale of its securities. In effect, Treasury payments are transfers from its commercial bank accounts to the bank accounts of the public.

The Treasury has no use for, and does not accumulate, balances in its commercial bank accounts in excess of its near-term payment obligations. It sells or redeems securities only as required to balance its inflows against outflows. On average, government spending does not affect the aggregate bank deposits of the private sector.

You might also like