Download as ppt, pdf, or txt
Download as ppt, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 45

ECE 333

Green Electric Energy

Lecture 14
Engineering Economics

Professor Tom Overbye


Department of Electrical and
Computer Engineering
Announcements

Be reading Chapter 5

Homework 6 is due Oct 22. It is 4.9, 5.2, 5.4, 5.6, 5.11

Wind Farm field trip will be on Nov 5 from about 8am to 4pm – turn in forms to sign up.

Campus Wind Turbine Project: Let your voice be heard! If you would like to email your student senators
• with your wind turbine views some folks to talk with are Bradley Tran (president-iss@illinois.edu), Bobby
Gregg (bobby.gregg@gmail.com), Melanie Cornell (cornell4@illinois.edu)
Energy Economic Concepts
(From Prof. Gross)
• The economic evaluation of a renewable energy resource
requires a meaningful quantification of cost elements
– fixed costs
– variable costs
• We use engineering economics notions for this purpose
since they provide the means to compare on a consistent
basis
– two different projects; or,
– the costs with and without a given project
Time Value of Money

• Basic notion: a dollar today is not the same as a


dollar in a year
• We represent the time value of money by the
standard approach of discounted cash flows
• The notation is
P = principal
i = interest value
• The convention we use is that payments occur at the
end of each period (e.o.p.)
Simple Example

loan P for 1 year


repay P + iP = P ( 1 + i ) at the end of 1 year
year 0 P
year 1 P (1 + i)

loan P for n years


year 0 P
year 1 (1 + i) P repay/reborrow
year 2 ( 1 + i )2 P repay/reborrow
M 3
year ( 1M+ i )3 P M
repay/reborrow
.
year n ( 1 + i )n P repay
Compound Interest
e.o.p. amount owed interest for amount owed for next period
next period
0 P Pi P + Pi = P(1+i )

1 P(1+i ) P(1+i ) i P(1+i ) + P(1+i ) i = P(1+i ) 2

2 P(1+i ) 2 P(1+i ) 2 i P(1+i ) 2 + P(1+i ) 2 i = P(1+i ) 3

3 P(1+i ) 3 P(1+i ) 3 i P(1+i ) 3 + P(1+i ) 3 i = P(1+i ) 4

M M
n-1 P(1+i ) n-1 P(1+i ) n-1 i P(1+i ) n-1 + P(1+i ) n-1 i = P(1+i ) n

n P(1+i ) n

The value in the last column for the e.o.p. (k-1) provides the value in
the first column for the e.o.p. k (e.o.p. is end of period)
Terminology/Overview

• Cash flow diagrams


Incoming cash flow

0 1 2 3 4
Outward cash flows
Present

• Common conversion factors


– Present Value- (P|A,i%,n) and (P|F,i%,n)
– Future Value- (F|A,i%,n) and (F|P,i%,n)
– Capital Recovery Factor- (A|P,i%,n)
Cash Flows

• A cash flow is a transfer of an amount A t from one


entity to another at e.o.p. time t
• A cash-flow set { A0 , A1 , A2 ,..., An} corresponds to the set
of times { 0 ,1, 2,..., n}
• The convention for Ex.
cash flows is
+ inflow I take out a loan
− outflow 0 1 2 3 4
I make equal repayments

• Each cash flow has (1) amount, (2) time, and (3) sign
Cash Flows

• Given a cash-flow set { A , A , A ,..., A }


0 1 2 n we
define the future worth F n of the cash flow set at e.o.y.
n as n

∑ A ( 1 + i)
n− t
Fn = t
t =0

A0 A1 A2 At A n-2 A n-1 An

... ...
0 1 2 t n–2 n–2 n
Cash Flows

• Note that each cash flow A t in the set contributes


differently to F n
A0 ( 1 + i )
n
A0 →
A1 ( 1 + i )
n−1
A1 →
A2 ( 1 + i )
n− 2
A2 →
M M
At ( 1 + i )
n− t
At →
M M
An → An
Discount Rate

• The interest rate i is typically referred to as the


discount rate and is denoted by d
• In converting a future amount F to a present worth
P we can view the discount rate as the interest rate
that can be earned from the best investment
alternative
• A postulated savings of $ 10,000 in a project in 5
years is worth at present

= 10,000 ( 1 + d )
−5
P = F5 β 5
Discount Rate

• For d = 0.1, P = $ 6,201,


while for d = 0.2, P = $ 4,019
• In general, the lower the discount factor, the
higher the present worth
• The present worth of a set of costs under a given
discount rate is called the life-cycle costs
Cash Flow Example

• Find the future worth of cash flows at the end of year 5


d = %12 $ 3,000

F5=?
0 1 2 3 4 5
year

$ 2,000 $ 2,000

Answer: outflow of $2571


Cash Flows

• Single-payment compound amount factor-


( 1+ i)
n

• Single-payment present worth factor-


β @( 1 + i ) = ( 1+ i)
−1 −n
β n

• n is typically in years and need not be an integer value


Cash Flows

• We define the present worth P of the cash flow set as


n n

∑A β ∑ A ( 1 + i)
−t
P = t
t
= t
t =0 t =0
• Note that n

∑ A ( 1 + i)
−t
P = t
t =0

∑ A ( 1 + i ) (11 4+ i4) 2( 14+4i) 3


−t n −n
= t
t =0
1
Cash Flows
cont’d n
P = ( 1 + i ) ∑ At ( 1 + i )
−n n −t

142 4 3 t =0
1 4 42 4 43
β n
F n

= β n Fn
or equivalently

Fn = ( 1 + i ) P
n

This is the lump equivalent sum at the end of n periods.


F is the future worth, and P is the present worth
Example 1

• Consider a loan of $4,000 at 8% interest to be repaid in


two installments
– $ 1,000 and interest at the e.o.y. (end of year) 1
– $ 3,000 and interest at the e.o.y. 4
• The cash flows are
– e.o.y. 1: 1000 + 4000 (.08) = $ 1,320
– e.o.y. 4: 3000 (1 + .08 ) 3 = $ 3,779.14
• Note that the loan is made in year 0 present dollars,
but the repayments are in year 1 and
year 4 future dollars
Example 2

• Given that
P = $1,000 and i = .12

• Then we say that for the cost of money of 12%, P


and F are equivalent in the sense that $1,000 today
has the same worth as $1,762.34 in 5 years

P ( 1 + i) = $1,000( 1 + .12)
5 5
= $1,762.34 = F
Example 3

• Consider an investment that returns


$1,000 at the e.o.y. 1
rate at which
$2,000 at the e.o.y. 2 money can be
freely lent or
i = 10%
borrowed
• We evaluate P
P = $ 1,000 ( 1 + .1) + $ 2,000( 1 + .1)
−1 −2

142 43 142 43
β β 2

= $ 909.9 + $ 1,652.09 = $ 2,561.98


Net Present Value (NPV) for Example 3

• Next, suppose that this investment requires $ 2,400


now. At 10%, the investment has a net present value
(NPV ) of
NPV = $ 2,561.98 – $ 2,400 = $ 161.98
$ 1,000 $ 2,000
$ 2,561.98
0 1 2
$ 2,400 year

NPV=$ 161.98 { 0 1 2
Uniform Cash Flow Set

• Consider the cash-flow set { A0 , A1 , A2 ,..., An} with

At = A t = 1, 2,..., n
• Such a set is called an equal payment cash flow set
• Each payment can be thought of as a future value and
the results will be the same
• We compute the present worth
n n
P = ∑ At β
t =1
t
= A ∑ β t = Aβ 1 + β + β 2 + ... + β n− 1 
t =1
Uniform Cash Flow Set, cont.

• Now, for 0 < β < 1 , we have the identity



1
∑β j
=
1−β

∑β
j
j =0
• It follows that j=0

1 + β + ... + β n−1 = ∑ β
j =0
j
− β n

 1 + β + β 2
+... + β n −1
+...

= ( 1−β n ) ∑ β j

j =0
1− β n
=
1− β
Uniform Cash Flow Set, cont.

• Therefore  1 − β n
P = A β 
 1− β 
β = (1 + d)
−1
• But and so
1 d
1−β = 1− = = βd
1+ d 1+d
• We write P = A 1 − β n

d
1− βn
• We call the equal payment series present
d value function
Uniform Cash Flows, PVF

1−β n
1 − (1 + d ) −n
(1 + d ) − 1
n
= =
d d d (1 + d )n
this is also written as (P|A,d%,n)
In the News: States Not Meeting
Renewable Energy Goals
• USA Today had an article last week that discussed progress states
were making on meeting their renewable portfolio standards; 35
states have such goals
• There is no central clearing house on compliance, so the article
just discussed several examples
– NJ would like to have 1000MW of offshore wind by 2012, but will miss
that by about a year
– CA has a 20% goal by 2010, but won’t achieve that until 2013 or 2014
– AZ planned to get 0.3% from solar by 2009, but probably won’t achieve
that until 2011

www.usatoday.com/money/industries/energy/2009-10-08-altenergy_N.htm
California and Solar

• In California Gov Schwarzenegger signed two solar energy


bills this week that will help make solar energy more cost
effective for consumers (with solar).
– AB 920 requires utility companies to pay customers for any surplus
electricity they produce from solar or wind (previously they had to
give it back any surplus for free)
– AB 32 creates an above-market tariff, called a “feed-in-tariff” that
requires the state’s utilities to buy solar electricity from 1.5 to 3.0
MW units at rates above what they would pay for conventional
sources
Equivalence

• We consider two cash-flow sets


{ A : t = 0,1, 2,..., n}
a
t and { A : t = 0,1, 2,..., n}
b
t

under a given discount rate d


• We say are equivalent cash-flow sets if
{A }a
t and { A } b
t
their future worths (or their net worths at any point in
time) are identical.
Equivalence, Example

• Consider the two cash-flow sets 8,200.40


under d = 7%

2000 2000 2000 2000 2000

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 0 1 2
a b
Equivalence, cont.
7
• We compute P a = 2000 ⋅ ∑ β t
= 7162.33
t =3

and P b = 8200.40 ⋅ β 2 = 7162.33

• Therefore, { A a } and { A b} are equivalent cash flow sets


t t
under d = 7%
Example

• Consider the set of cash flows illustrated below


$ 400
$ 300
$ 200 $ 200

3
0 1 2 4 5 6 7 8

d = 6%
$ 300
Example, cont.

• We compute F 8 at t = 8 for d = 6%
F8 = 300 ( 1 + .06) − 300( 1 + .06)
7 5
+
200 ( 1 + .06) + 400( 1 + .06)
4 2
+ 200
= $ 951.56

• We next compute P
P = 300 ( 1 + .06) − 300( 1 + .06)
−1 −3

+ 200 ( 1 + .06 ) + 400( 1 + .06) + 200( 1 + .06)


−4 −6 −8

= $ 597.04
• We check that for d = 6%
F8 = 597.04 ( 1 + .06) = $ 951.56
8
Motor Purchase Example

• We consider the purchase of two 100-hp motors – a


and b – to be used over a 20-year period; the discount
rate is 10%
• The relative merits of a and b are
motor costs ( $ ) load ( kW )

a 2,400 79.0

b 2,900 77.5

• The motor is used 1,600 hours per year and electricity


costs are constant at 0.08 $/kWh
Motor Purchase Example, motor a

• We evaluate yearly energy costs over 20 years for motor a


A a = ( 79.0 kW ) ( 1600 h / yr) ( .08 $ / kWh) = $ 10,112/ yr

0 1 2 t 19 20
... ... ...
Aa Aa Aa Aa Aa

$2400

20

∑ ( 1.1of) motor
−t
• We a
= 2, 400
P evaluate the+present
10,112worth = $a88, 489
t =1
Motor Purchase Example, motor b

• We evaluate yearly energy costs over 20 years for motor b


A b = ( 77.5 kW ) ( 1600 h / yr) ( .08 $ / kWh) = $ 9, 920 / yr
0 1 2 t 19 20
... ... ...
Ab Ab Ab Ab Ab

$2900

20
• ∑ ( 1.1) of
−t
WePnext
b
= evaluate
2, 900 + the present
9, 920 worth = motor b
$ 87, 354
t =1
Motor Purchase Example, cont.

• Comparing the present worths of motors a and b gives the


following:

P a − P b = 88, 489 − 87, 354 = $ 1,135

• Therefore, the purchase of motor b results in a savings of $


1,135 compared to motor a due to the use of the smaller
load motor under the specified 10% discount rate

• What if it were a generator instead of a motor?


Infinite Horizon Cash-Flow Sets

• Consider a uniform cash-flow set with n → ∞

{ At = A : t = 0, 1, 2, ... }
• Then,
P = A
( 1 − β n
) A
1
d n →∞ d
For an infinite horizon uniform cash-flow set

A
= d
P
Infinite Horizon Cash-Flow Sets, cont.

• We may view d as the capital recovery factor with the


following interpretation:

For an initial investment of P,

dP = A
is the annual amount recovered in terms of
returns on investment
Internal Rate of Return

• We consider a cash-flow set


{A t = A : t = 0, 1, 2, ... }
• The value of d for which
n
P = ∑ t =0
A β
t =0
t

is called the internal rate of return (IRR)


• The IRR is a measure of how fast we recover an
investment or stated differently, the speed with which
the returns recover an investment
Internal Rate of Return Example

• Consider the following cash-flow set


$6,000 $6,000 $6,000 $6,000 $6,000
0

1 2 3 4 8

$30,000
Internal Rate of Return

• The present value

1− β 8
P = − 30,000 + 6,000 =0
d
has the (non-obvious) solution of d equal to about 12%.
• The interpretation is that under a 12% discount rate, the present
value of the cash flow set is 0 and so 12% is the IRR for the given
cash- flow set
– The investment makes sense as long as other investments yield less than
12%.
Internal Rate of Return

• Consider an infinite horizon simple investment


A A A
...
0 1 2 n
I
A ratio of annual return to
• Therefore d = I initial investment
• For I = $ 1,000 and A = $ 200, d = 20% and we
interpret that the returns capture 20% of the investment
each year or equivalently that we have a simple
payback period of 5 years
Efficient Refrigerator Example

• A more efficient refrigerator incurs an investment of


additional $ 1,000 but provides $ 200 of energy savings
annually
• For a lifetime of 10 years, the IRR is computed from the
solution of
1− β 10
0 = − 1,000 + 200
d
or The solution of this equation
1− β 10
= 5 requires either an iterative
d approach or a value looked
up from a table
Efficient Refrigerator Example, cont.

•IRR tables show that 1 − β 10


= 5.02
d d = 15%
and so the IRR is approximately 15%
If the refrigerator has an expected lifetime of 15 years this
value becomes

1 − β 15
= 5.00
d d = 18.4%

As was mentioned earlier, the value is 20% if it lasts forever


Impacts of Inflation

• Inflation is a general increase in the level of prices in an


economy; equivalently, we may view inflation as a general
decline in the value of the purchasing power of money
• Inflation is measured using prices: different products may
have distinct escalation rates
• Typically, indices such as the CPI – the consumer price index
– use a market basket of goods and services as a proxy for the
entire U.S. economy
– reference basis is the year 1967 with the price of $ 100 for the basket
(L 0); in the year 1990, the same basket cost $ 374 (L 23 )
Figuring Average Rate of Inflation

• Calculate average inflation rate e from 1967 to 1990


374
( 1 + e) =
23
= 3.74
100 Current
ln ( 3.74 )
ln ( 1 + e ) = → e = 0.059% (1/2009)
23 basket
value is
about 632.

Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/File:US_Historical_Inflation.svg

You might also like