Mean-Reverting Models in Financial and Energy Markets: Anatoliy Swishchuk

You might also like

Download as ppt, pdf, or txt
Download as ppt, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 66

Mean-Reverting Models

in
Financial and Energy Markets
Anatoliy Swishchuk
Mathematical and
Computational Finance
Laboratory,
Department of Mathematics and
Statistics, U of C
5th North-South Dialog,
Edmonton, AB, April 30, 2005

Outline
Mean-Reverting Models (MRM): Deterministic
vs. Stochastic
MRM in Finance: Variances (Not Asset Prices)
MRM in Energy Markets: Asset Prices
Some Results: Swaps, Swaps with Delay, Option
Pricing Formula (one-factor models)
Drawback of One-Factor Models
Future Work

Mean-Reversion Effect
Violin (or Guitar) String Analogy: if we pluck the
violin (or guitar) string, the string will revert to its
place of equilibrium
To measure how quickly this reversion back to
the equilibrium location would happen we had to
pluck the string
Similarly, the only way to measure mean
reversion is when the variances of asset prices
in financial markets and asset prices in energy
markets get plucked away from their non-event
levels and we observe them go back to more or
less the levels they started from

The Mean-Reversion Deterministic Process

Mean-Reverting Plot (a=4.6,L=2.5)

Meaning of Mean-Reverting Parameter


The greater the mean-reverting parameter value,
a, the greater is the pull back to the equilibrium
level
For a daily variable change, the change in time,
dt, in annualized terms is given by 1/365
If a=365, the mean reversion would act so
quickly as to bring the variable back to its
equilibrium within a single day
The value of 365/a gives us an idea of how
quickly the variable takes to get back to the
equilibrium-in days

Mean-Reversion Stochastic Process

Mean-Reverting Models in
Financial Markets
Stock (asset) Prices follow
geometric Brownian motion
The Variance of Stock Price
follows Mean-Reverting Models

Mean-Reverting Models in
Energy Markets

Asset Prices follow MeanReverting Stochastic Processes

Heston Model for Stock Price and


Variance
Model for Stock Price (geometric Brownian motion):

or

deterministic interest rate,


follows Cox-Ingersoll-Ross (CIR) process

Standard Brownian Motion and


Geometric Brownian Motion
Standard Brownian motion

Geometric Brownian motion

Heston Model: Variance follows meanreverting (CIR) process

or

Cox-Ingersoll-Ross (CIR) Model for Stochastic


Variance (Volatility)

The model is a mean-reverting process, which pushes


away from zero to keep it positive.
The drift term is a restoring force which always points
towards the current mean value .

Swaps
Security-a piece of paper representing a promise
Basic Securities
Stock (a security
representing partial
ownership of a
company)

Bonds (bank
accounts)

Derivative Securities
Option (right but not obligation to
do something in the future)
Forward contract (an agreement
to buy or sell something in a
future date for a set price:
obligation)

Swaps-agreements between
two counterparts to exchange
cash flows in the future to a
prearrange formula: obligation

Variance and Volatility Swaps


Forward contract-an agreement to buy or sell something
at a future date for a set price (forward price)
Variance is a measure of the uncertainty of a stock price.
Volatility (standard deviation) is the square root of the variance
(the amount of noise, risk or variability in stock price)
Variance=(Volatility)^2

Volatility swaps are


forward contracts on
future realized stock
volatility

Variance swaps are


forward contract on
future realized stock
variance

Realized Continuous Variance and


Volatility
Realized (or Observed) Continuous Variance:

Realized Continuous Volatility:

where

is a stock volatility ,

is expiration date or maturity.

Variance Swaps
A Variance Swap is a forward contract on realized
variance.
Its payoff at expiration is equal to (Kvar is the
delivery price for variance and N is the notional
amount in $ per annualized variance point)

Volatility Swaps
A Volatility Swap is a forward contract on
realized volatility.
Its payoff at expiration is equal to:

How does the Volatility Swap Work?

Example: Payoff for Volatility and Variance


Swaps
For Volatility Swap:
a) volatility increased to 21%:
Strike price Kvol =18% ; Realized Volatility=21%;
N =$50,000/(volatility point).
Payment(HF to D)=$50,000(21%-18%)=$150,000.
b) volatility decreased to 12%:
Payment(D to HF)=$50,000(18%-12%)=$300,000.
For Variance Swap:
Kvar = (18%)^2; N = $50,000/(one volatility point)^2.

Valuing of Variance Swap for


Stochastic Volatility
Value of Variance Swap (present value):

where E is an expectation (or mean value), r is interest rate.


To calculate variance swap we need only E{V},
where

and

Calculation E[V]

Valuing of Volatility Swap


for Stochastic Volatility
Value of volatility swap:

We use second order Taylor expansion for square root function.


To calculate volatility swap we need not only E{V} (as in the
case of variance swap), but also Var{V}.

Calculation of Var[V]
(continuation)

After calculations:

Finally we obtain:

Numerical Example 1:
S&P60 Canada Index

Numerical Example: S&P60 Canada


Index
We apply the obtained analytical solutions to
price a swap on the volatility of the S&P60
Canada Index for five years (January 1997February 2002)
These data were kindly presented to author
by Raymond Theoret (University of Quebec,
Montreal, Quebec,Canada) and Pierre
Rostan (Bank of Montreal, Montreal,
Quebec,Canada)

Logarithmic Returns
Logarithmic returns are used in practice to define discrete
sampled variance and volatility
Logarithmic Returns:

where

Statistics on Log-Returns of
S&P60 Canada Index for 5 years
(1997-2002)

Histograms of Log. Returns


for S&P60 Canada Index

S&P60 Canada Index Volatility Swap

Realized Continuous Variance for


Stochastic Volatility with Delay

Stock Price

Initial Data
deterministic function

Equation for Stochastic Variance with


Delay (Continuous-Time GARCH Model)
Our (Kazmerchuk, Swishchuk, Wu (2002) The Option Pricing Formula for
Security Markets with Delayed Response) first attempt was:

This is a continuous-time analogue of its discrete-time GARCH(1,1) model

J.-C. Duan remarked that it is important to incorporate the expectation of


log-return into the model

Stochastic Volatility with Delay

Main Features of this Model


Continuous-time analogue of GARCH(1,1)
Mean-reversion
Does not contain another Wiener process
Complete market
Incorporates the expectation of log-return

Valuing of Variance Swap for


Stochastic Volatility with Delay
Value of Variance Swap (present value):

where E is an expectation (or mean value), r is interest rate.

To calculate variance swap we need only E{V},

where

and

Continuous-Time GARCH Model

Deterministic Equation for


Expectation of Variance with Delay

There is no explicit solution for this equation besides stationary solution.

Valuing of Variance Swap with


Delay in General Case
We need to find EP*[Var(S)]:

Numerical Example 2: S&P60 Canada


Index (1997-2002)

Dependence of Variance Swap with Delay


on Maturity (S&P60 Canada Index)

Variance Swap with Delay (S&P60 Canada Index)

Numerical Example 3: S&P500


(1990-1993)

Dependence of Variance Swap with Delay


on Maturity (S&P500)

Variance Swap with Delay (S&P500 Index)

Mean-Reverting Models in Energy


Markets

Explicit Solution for MRAM

Explicit Option Pricing Formula for European


Call Option under Physical Measure
(assumption: W(phi_t^-1)-Gaussian?)

Parameters:

Mean-Reverting Risk-Neutral Asset Model


(MRRNAM)

Transformations:

Explicit Solution for MRRNAM

Explicit Option Pricing Formula for European


Call Option under Risk-Neutral Measure

Numerical Example: AECO Natural Gas Index


(1 May 1998-30 April 1999)
(Bos, Ware, Pavlov: Quantitative Finance, 2002)

Variance for New Process


W(phi_t^-1)

Mean-Value for MRRNAM

Mean-Value for MRRNAM

Volatility for MRRNAM

Price C(T) of European Call Option (S=1)


(Sonny Kushwaha, Haskayne School of Business, U of
C, (my student, AMAT371))
1

0.9

0.8

0.7

C(T)

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.2

0.1

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5
T

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

European Call Option Price for MRM


(Sonny Kushwaha, Haskayne School of Business, U of
C, (my student, AMAT371))

L. Bos, T. Ware (U of C) and Pavlov (U of Auckland, NZ)


(Quantitative Finance, V. 2 (2002), 337-345)

Comparison
(approximation vs. explicit formula)

Conclusions
Variances of Asset Prices in Financial Markets follow
Mean-Reverting Models
Asset Prices in Energy Markets follow Mean-Reverting
Models
We can price variance and volatility swaps for an asset in
financial markets (for Heston model + models with delay)
We can price options for an asset in energy markets
Drawbacks: 1) one-factor models (L is a constant)
2) W(phi_t^-1)-Gaussian process
Future work: 1) consider two-factor models: S (t) and L
(t) (L->L (t)) (possibly with jumps) (analytical approach)
2) 1) with probabilistic approach
3) to study the process W(\phi_t^-1)

Drawback of One-Factor MeanReverting Models


The long-term mean L remains fixed over time:
needs to be recalibrated on a continuous basis
in order to ensure that the resulting curves are
marked to market
The biggest drawback is in option pricing: results
in a model-implied volatility term structure that
has the volatilities going to zero as expiration
time increases (spot volatilities have to be
increased to non-intuitive levels so that the long
term options do not lose all the volatility value-as
in the marketplace they certainly do not)

Future work I.
(Joint Working Paper with T. Ware:
Analytical Approach (Integro - PDE),
Whittaker functions)

Future Work II
(Probabilistic Approach: Change of
Time Method).

Acknowledgement
Id like to thank very much to Robert Elliott,
Tony Ware, Len Bos, Gordon Sick, and
Graham Weir for valuable suggestions and
comments, and to all the participants of the
Lunch at the Lab (weekly seminar, usually
Each Thursday, at the Mathematical and
Computational Finance Laboratory) for
discussion and remarks during all my talks in
the Lab.
Id also like to thank very much to PIMS for
partial support of this talk

Thank you for your


attention!

You might also like