Introduction To Entrepreneurship

You might also like

Download as ppt, pdf, or txt
Download as ppt, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 42

Introduction to Entrepreneurship

Lecture 13
’Hard’ Support: Science Parks
Support Knowledge-Based Firms?

• Significant growth in new firms, particularly consumer


services firms
• Focus on new firm ‘quality’ and high growth ventures
• Increase the supply of ‘knowledge-based’ firms whose
competitive advantage is ‘knowledge’ and not low
price
• Initiatives to increase the supply of firms from Higher
Education Institutes (HEIs) and research laboratories
Knowledge-Based Firms: Benefits

• Encourage national economic development


• Broaden the industrial base of regions
• Improve the competitive capability of industry
• Job generation and wealth creation
• Reduce local new firm displacement – ‘born-
global’ firms that export
Neo-Classical Location Theory
• Location of individual firms is influenced by direct economic costs (Weber,
1929; Smith, 1981):
• Distance from markets, transport costs, labour costs and agglomeration
economies
• Cost and availability of premises
• Cost and availability of skilled labour
• Availability of financial grants and subsidies
• Provision of complementary services to overcome an entrepreneur’s
weaknesses in core business skills
• Environmental quality
• Presence of a local HEI (MacGregor et al., 1986; Flynn 1993)
Behaviourial Location Theory
• “…the role of people throughout the process of technological
change is crucial” (Malecki, 1991, p.372)
• Satisfying rather than profit maximising can be a key factor
influencing the location decisions made by entrepreneurs (Autio
and Kauranen, 1994)
• Consider the influence and effect of uncertainty (or lack of full
information) on decision-making
• Gate-keepers (i.e., Science Park managers) can act as a
formal mechanism (Johannisson et al., 1994) to reduce
uncertainty (and associated costs)
Gate-Keepers / Science Park Managers

• Minimize some of the liabilities of firm small size


and youthfulness (Van de Ven, 1993)
• Channel information to a firm with limited
legitimacy
• Broaden business networks
• Facilitate access to resources from HEIs, banks,
venture capitalists and enterprise agencies
Structural Theory

• Structure of an entire industrial system has a key


role influencing the location of economic activity
• Sought to explain locational agglomeration
• An innovative milieu (Aydalot and Keeble, 1988) and
the notion of an industrial district (Piore and Sabel,
1984)
• Non-physical resources, proximity, relational capital
and co-operation and learning influence the
development of territorial synergy (Maillat, 1995)
Structural Theory (II)
• Combination of clusters of science-based knowledge,
together with institutions and skilled labour encourage
innovation (Castells and Hall, 1994)
• Science Park can provide and gain access to structural
elements which encourage synergy between technology-
based firms
• Institutional factors within a Science Park locale (Giddens,
1979) can provide a context for acquiring knowledge and
experience and for the routinising of many activities (Thrift,
1996)
Network Theory

• Model of emerging networks focusing upon the relational


structure of exchange between individuals (Johannisson et al.,
1994)
• Science Park is a formal institution that is deliberately created
to deal with collective concerns
• Formal administrative structure of a Science Park is created to
manage the property and / or to manage the delivery of
services
• Science Park management agreement can influence the ability
of firms to acquire services and resources
Social and Business Networks
• A firm’s social network:
– Genuine dialogue between firms on Science Parks is due to talk
networks (an instrumental communication dimension and
socialising based on affection)
– Acquaintances networks (a potential for solicited and unsolicited
expressive exchange) are encouraged by peers or gate-keepers
who can legitimize the activities of academic entrepreneurs who
are managerially inexperienced
• A firm’s business network:
– Commercial networks (access to local product and resource
markets)
– Professional networks (access to problem-oriented information
retrieval)
Sponsored Environments
• Address attitudinal, resource and operational barriers
• Property-based Science Parks (Westhead and Batstone, 1998):
– Reduce uncertainty and risk
– Provide resources
– Reduce direct costs
– Increase flow of information
– Encourage development of business networks
– Encourage links with adjacent university and large firms
• Universities – new income streams, student placements, student
employment in local region
Science Parks: Definition

• United Kingdom Science Park Association (UKSPA, 1999)


• Encourages and supports the start-up and incubation of
innovation-led, high-growth, knowledge-based businesses
• Provides an environment where larger and international
businesses can develop specific and close interactions with a
particular centre of knowledge creation for their mutual
benefit
• Has formal and operational links with centres of knowledge
creation such as universities, higher education institutes and
research organisations
Science Park Developers: Assumptions

• Firms desire high specification and flexible premises


• Firms desire landscaped environments
• Firms are concerned with business image and want
to increase their credibility and status
• Firms want to be linked to a local HEI
• Firms want to co-operate with other tenants
• Firms are prepared to pay a ‘rent premium’
What is Provided on a Science Park?

• Intellectual and physical infrastructure that


includes:
– Built environment
– Immediate surroundings
– Communications, telecommunication, IT, business
services and business support services

• Management support actively engaged in the


transfer of both technology and business skills
Objectives of Science Parks
(Massey et al., 1992, p.21)
• Promote Higher Education Institute (HEI) / industry
linkages and the transfer of technology from HEIs to
Science Park firms (linear innovation model is
assumed)
• Promote the formation of new technology-based firms
• Encourage spin-off firms started by academics
• Encourage the growth of existing technology-based firms
• Attract firms involved in leading-edge technologies
Supply-side Perspective

• Create synergy between firms


• Improve the performance of the local economy
• Improve the image of the location, particularly for
areas of industrial decline
• Create new jobs directly (and indirectly)
• Enhance the competitiveness of new and existing
firms in the region
Science Parks in the UK
• Silicon Valley (San Francisco, USA) role model; 3,000 electronic
manufacturing firms; 5,000 firms providing producer services
(research laboratories, design, market research, recruitment, venture
capital)
• 85% of firms in the area employed less than 50 people (Castells and
Hall, 1994)
• Stanford University in Palo Alto and Massachusetts Institute of
Technology (MIT) in USA role models (Saxenian, 1994)
• In 1972, Cambridge and Heriot-Watt Science Parks
• 7 Science Parks (1983), 32 (1989) and 46 (1999)
• Most HEIs now have an adjacent Science Park
Management Strategies
(Carter, 1989; Grayson, 1993)
• University led and funded strategy: Established and managed by
a HEI on its own (this is the least common model) - Cambridge,
Heriot-Watt and Surrey
• Joint venture company strategy: Run as a separate legal entity
but a continuing role for the HEI and other investors - Aston
(Birmingham Technology Limited), Southampton (Chilworth
Centre Limited) and Warwick (University of Warwick Science Park
Limited)
• Co-operative venture strategy: Partners work together within a
flexible and informal framework. Local authority or development
agency leader. Least input from the HEI. Most common strategy
- Aberystwyth, Antrim, Durham and Stirling Science Parks
Management Agreements
(Grayson, 1993)

• Informal teams: Cheapest and most flexible


approach. Partners divide the various
management tasks between themselves. No full-
time, on-site management presence. Property
management may be carried out by a development
agency or local authority, and tenants have access
to the general business and technical advisory
services of the university, local authority,
enterprise agency etc. as required
Management Agreements (II)

• Single, on-site manager: Allows the build-up of


expertise relating to the specific needs of Science
Park firms. Property management generally
remains the responsibility of the local authority or
development agency. Science Park manager
chosen for his / her industrially related scientific
skills to enable the informed selection of tenants
and the promotion of technology transfer links,
other aspects of management may be neglected
Management Agreements (III)

• On-site management company: Formal integrated


management structure will give a more secure
basis for long term development. Management
team include representatives from all the Science
Park partners and provide a wide range of full time
tenant support services as well as undertaking
property management and marketing (e.g., Aston
and Warwick Science Parks)
Services Provided by Science Parks

• Management should go beyond tenant selection,


lettings, rent collection and rent review negotiation
• Provide a supportive environment (Flynn 1993) to
ensure rental growth and reduce business closures
• Jointly used services can help firms to reduce their
fixed overhead costs (Sternberg 1990)
• Flexible leasing agreements and the provision of
units of various sizes
Services Provided (II)

• Proactively stimulate technology transfer and promote


links between the local HEI and tenant firms through visits
from a HEI’s Industrial Liaison Officer
• Seminars and magazines to raise awareness of the HEI’s
resources and skills
• Shared social and recreational facilities facilitate informal
contacts between HEI and Science Park employees
• Provision of business advice and services related to
financial and marketing skills and intellectual property
protection
Services Provided (III)

• Provide training or use skills of HEI business school


• Encourage tenants to utilize the local HEI’s library service in
order to gain access to the latest technical and commercial
information
• Provide finance (i.e., Aston Science Park Fund) or act as
brokers linking firms to formal and informal sources of finance
(Westhead and Storey, 1997)
• Advice from the Science Park manager (i.e., gate-keeper) can
legitimize the activities of entrepreneurs and can increase and
diversify an entrepreneur’s networks
Demand-side Perspective
• Location decisions reported by owners of independent Science Park (n
= 46) and off-Park firms (n = 48)
• Science Park firms were significantly more likely to emphasize
(Westhead and Batstone, 1998):
– ‘prestige and image of the overall site’ (83% of Science Park firms
compared with 33% of off-Park firms)
– ‘provision of on-site management and common services’ (48%: 6%)
– ‘access to facilities of HEI / centre of research’ (44%: 0%)
– ‘prestige of being linked to the HEI / centre of research’ (37%: 0%)
– ‘scope for attracting graduate HEI staff’ (28%: 6%)
– ‘friendly atmosphere among tenants on site’ (22%: 8%)
Demand-side Perspective (II)
• Off-Park firms emphasized (but not significantly):

– ‘cost of premises’ (46% compared with 60%)


– ‘the firm was already based in the area’ (37%
compared with 56%)
‘Managed’ Science Parks

• ‘Managed’ Science Park has a (generally full-time)


manager on site whose principal task is to manage
the Park (Westhead and Storey, 1994)

• UKSPA identified: Aberdeen, Aberystwyth,


Cambridge, Highfields (Nottingham), Listerhills
(Bradford) and Loughborough
‘Managed’ Park Firm Profile

• Assisted areas
• Firms dependent on a small number of customers
• Firms provide products / services perceived to be risky /
leading edge
• Firms wanted to:
– Address dependency problems
– Increase legitimacy
– Access to low cost producer services
– Gate-keeper to expand networks
‘Non-Managed’ Park Firm Profile

• Older and larger firms; manufacturing products


• Taken out patents to protect their products
• Do not require a proactive gate-keeper who facilitates
producer services
• Firms wanted to:
– Status and prestige
– Links with HEIs and multinational firms
– Diverse social and business networks
‘Managed’ and ‘non-Managed’ Firms
Westhead and Batstone (1999)
• ‘Managed’ firms (6.7) used twice as many facilities as ‘non-
managed’ firms (3.3)
• Over 41% of ‘managed’ firms used:
– Reception (77%), conference rooms (75%)
– Mail service (73%), business services (64%)
– Photocopying services (54%),
– Restaurant / cafeteria (52%),
– Audio-visual equipment (48%)
– Telephone answering service (46%)
– Fax / telex service (43%)
Role of Science Park Manager
• Significantly more respondents on ‘managed’ parks suggested
the SP manager had a high level of involvement with regard to
the following roles:
– 'approachability: how easy is s/he to talk to in person'
– 'accessibility: how easy is s/he to get to see‘
– 'does s/he run the science park efficiently on the whole‘
– 'how effective has the management been in responding to your
property needs‘
– 'how well informed is s/he on subjects of interest to your firm‘
– 'does s/he provide a useful range of services for companies on site‘
– 'does s/he provide a useful facility to sources of information'
Science Park Manager Concerns

• Science Park managers on ‘managed’ parks


effectively respond to the property needs of
firms

• Less effective in providing signposting facilities


to sources of information and HEI services /
skills
Conclusions

• Entrepreneurs located on ‘managed’ and ‘non-managed’


Science Parks appreciated the benefits provided by
property-based initiatives
• Owners of ‘non-managed’ and ‘managed’ Science Parks
are committed to the needs of technology-based firms
• Science Parks are beacons to encourage the spontaneous
clustering of technology-based firms
• Science Parks provide premises and postal addresses that
can increase the legitimacy of new and small technology-
based firms
Conclusions (II)

• Owners of ‘managed’ and ‘non-managed’ Science


Parks provide essential resources and services
• Owners of firms value a supportive environment
• Firms address some of the liabilities associated with
small firm size and youthfulness by expanding their
social and business networks
• Firms are prepared to pay a rental premium for a
prestige address to signal their increased legitimacy
and status
Conclusions (III)

• By linking with a local HEI, Science Park firms are able to


minimize the direct personal cost (and associated risk)
associated with R & D
• Managers of ‘managed’ Parks are less selective (and more
prepared to take risks) surrounding the choice of tenants
• Firms located on ‘managed’ Parks are not a homogeneous
entity
• Profiles of firms located on ‘managed’ and ‘non-managed’
Parks are not identical
Conclusions (IV)
• ‘Managed’ Parks selected to:
– Gain access to resources
– Access to low cost producer services
– Increase legitimacy
– Gate-keepers that actively expand networks

• ‘Managed’ Park firms used more services and appreciated the


role of the manager on site
• Established and resource rich firms located on ‘non-managed’
Parks did not require proactive gate-keepers but they benefited
from prestige, links with a local HEI and broadened networks
Conclusions (V)

• Science Park managers deal effectively with


property needs but were less likely to be seen as a
conduit to the facilities of the HEI

• Science Parks need to strengthen their managerial


function, in the sense of being seen to be less of a
property-based initiative
Conclusions (VI)

• “Faced with the magnitude of the task of innovation,


appendixing to the science park the role of innovation
‘seedbed’ or regional development ‘growth pole’ may
be an unrealistic expectation from a project that in
many instances is not much more than a real-estate
development. Thus, if there is some disappointment
in the fact that science parks are often not much more
than high-tech ‘islands’ with minimal interactions both
between themselves and with their neighbouring
universities, it could be that hopes were pitched too
high in the first place” (Felsenstein, 1994, p.108)
References
• Autio, E., and Kauranen, I. (1994). Technologist-Entrepreneurs Versus Non-Entrepreneurial
Technologists: Analysis of Motivational Trigger Factors. Entrepreneurship and Regional
Development, 6, pp.315-328.
• Aydalot, P., and Keeble, D. (Eds.). (1988). Technology, Industry and Innovative
Environments: The European Experience. London: Routledge.
• Carter, N. (1989). Science Parks Development and Management. London: The Estates Gazette
Limited.
• Castells, M., and Hall, P. (1994). Technopoles of the World: The Making of 21 st Century
Industrial Complexes. London: Routledge.
• Felsenstein, D. (1994). University-Related Science Parks - ‘Seedbeds’ or ‘Enclaves’ of
Innovation? Technovation, 14, pp.93-110.
• Flynn, D. M. (1993). A Critical Exploration of Sponsorship, Infrastructure, and New
Organizations. Small Business Economics, Vol. 5, pp.129-156.
• Giddens, A. (1979). Central Problems in Social Theory. Action, Structure and Contradiction in
Social Analysis. London: Macmillan
• Grayson, L. (1993). Science Parks: An Experiment in High Technology Transfer . London: The
British Library.
References (II)
• Johannisson, B., Alexanderson, O., Nowicki, K., and Senneseth, K. (1994). Beyond Anarchy and
Organization: Entrepreneurs in Contextual Networks, Entrepreneurship and Regional
Development, 6 (4), pp.329-356.
• MacGregor, B. D., Langridge, R. J., Adley, J., and Chapman, B. (1986). The Development of
High Technology Industry in Newbury District. Regional Studies, 20, pp.433-448.
• Maillat, D. (1995). Territorial Dynamic, Innovative Milieus and Regional Policy.
Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, 7, pp.157-165
• Malecki, E. J. (1991). Technology and Economic Development: The Dynamics of Local, Regional
and National Change. London: Longman.
• Massey, D., Quintas, P., and Wield, D. (1992). High Tech Fantasies: Science Parks in Society,
Science and Space. London: Routledge.
• Piore, M., and Sabel, C. (1984). The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity . New
York: Basic Books.
• Saxenian, A. (1994). Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon Valley and Route
128. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
• Smith, D. M. (1981). Industrial Location: An Economic Geographical Analysis. (Second Edition).
New York: John Wiley.
References (III)

• Sternberg, R. (1990). The Impact of Innovation Centres on Small


Technology-Based Firms: The Example of the Federal Republic of Germany.
Small Business Economics, 2, pp.105-118.
• Thrift, N. (1996). Spatial Formations. London: Sage Publications.
• UKSPA. (1996). UKSPA 96: The United Kingdom Science Park Association
Annual Report 1996. Birmingham: The United Kingdom Science Park
Association.
• Van de Ven, A. H. (1993). The Development of an Infrastructure for
Entrepreneurship. Journal of Business Venturing, 8, pp.211-230.
• Weber, A. (1929). Alfred Weber’s Theory of the Location of Industries.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
References (IV)

• Westhead, P. and Storey, D. J. (1994). An Assessment of Firms Located On


and Off Science Parks in the United Kingdom, London: HMSO.
• Westhead, P. and Storey, D. J. (1997). Financial Constraints on the Growth
of High Technology Small Firms in the United Kingdom. Applied Financial
Economics, 7, pp.197-201.
• Westhead, P. and Batstone, S. (1998). Independent Technology-Based
Firms: The Perceived Added Value of a Science Park Location. Urban
Studies, 35, pp.2197-2219.
• Westhead, P. and Batstone, S. (1999). Perceived Benefits of a Managed
Science Park Location for Independent Technology-Based Firms.
Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, 11, pp.129-154.

You might also like