Portfolio Theory and The Pricing of Risk

You might also like

Download as ppt, pdf, or txt
Download as ppt, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 42

Portfolio theory and the pricing of risk

(the short story)

1
Risk and the cost of capital
• How do we estimate today’s cost of capital?
– Bonds – relatively easy, it can be calculated from current prices
– Equities – tough, cannot be easily calculated from current prices

• As a bank, would you offer a loan to two different customers with the
same interest rate if one was twice as likely to not pay you back?
• It is rational to demand a higher rate of return on riskier loan.

• Similarly, it is rational to expect a higher rate of return on a riskier


investment

• Therefore, the cost of capital must be linked to the


risk of the firm and underlying project.

2
The big question…

• How does the cost of capital increase with risk?

• What is the nature of the relation between required


rates of return demanded by investors and the risk
of the asset in which they are investing?

3
The big question in picture form
E(r)

Rf

0
Risk
4
To address the issue we need some tools:

• Measure returns of portfolios


• Measure risk of portfolios
• Understand rational portfolio selection

5
Portfolio returns
• In general:
n
rp   wi ri
i 1

where
n

w
i 1
i 1

• wi is the percent of capital invested in asset i


• The portfolio return is a weighted average of the individual
asset returns
• Go to spreadsheet
6
Expected returns
• Most often, we are interested in what will happen.
• We can form our expectations in many ways…

– 1. from historical returns


• expect the past to happen again

– 2. from scenario analysis that considers stock’s


prospects across future events.

– 3. Using risk-premium and/or ad hoc expected return


models that include 1, 2, or many factors. <but not in
this class>
7
Scenario analysis
• Three basic steps:
– Consider the scenarios that may occur
– Attach probabilities and returns to each scenario
– calculate the E(r) scenario p(s) HPR
1 0.2 -0.05
2 0.3 0.25
3 0.4 0.05
4 0.1 -0.1
n
E ( r )   ps rs scenario p(s) HPR p(s)*HPR
1 0.2 -0.05 -0.01
s 1
2 0.3 0.25 0.075
3 0.4 0.05 0.02
4 0.1 -0.1 -0.01

sum 0.075

8
Measuring portfolio risk
• To measure portfolio risk, we need:
– 1. weights invested in each asset
– 2. standard deviation of each asset
– 3. The covariation or correlation between each asset

3.5

3
Growth of $1 investment

2.5

2
MCD
SBUX
1.5

0.5

0
0.00 20.00 40.00 60.00 80.00 100.00
Monthly Observation (1/2001-1/2009)
Correlation = .09

9
Covariance
• Ex-post, the covariance is measured as:
n

 ( r j ,i  r j )(rk ,i  rk )
 j ,k  i 1
n
• Ex-ante, the covariance is measured as:
N
 j ,k   pi (rj ,i  E (rj ))(rk ,i  E (rk ))
i 1

• What does covariance measure? Interpret a covariance?


• Correlation is a standardized covariance:
 j ,k
 j ,k 
 j k
10
Portfolio variance
• Skipping the proof, the 2-asset portfolio variance
is:
 p2  w12 12  w22 22  2 w1w2 1, 2

• The 3-asset portfolio variance


 p  w12 12  w22 22  w32 32  2w1w2 1, 2  2w1w3 1,3  2w2 w3 2,3
2

• The N-asset portfolio variance, N N


 
2
P ww  i j i, j
i 1 j 1

11
More portfolio variance
• In general, the portfolio variance has N2 terms
– N variance terms
– N2 - N covariance terms
• For an equally weighted portfolio:

 
lim  P2  average covariance
N 

• In a well-diversified portfolio, we only bear


“covariance risk”.
• This is risk is most often referred to as systematic
risk, it is the risk you can not diversify away
12
Diversification and systematic risk
portfolio

Systematic
risk

30 Stocks in
portfolio
13
Portfolio Selection

14
How should we select our portfolio?

• We should want to select assets such that we


expect to earn as much return as possible per unit
risk.

Maximize some expected-return/risk ratio

15
What defines our possible choices?
• If =1, then there is no benefit to diversification

24.00%

20.00%
wA E(RP) P 16.00%
B
-0.5 20.0% 26.5% 12.00%

E(R)
0.0 16.0 20.0 8.00%
A
0.5 12.0 13.5 4.00%
1.0 8.0 7.0 0.00%
1.5 4.0 0.5 0.00% 10.00% 20.00% 30.00%
Std. Dev.

16
What defines our possible choices?

If ρ=-1
we can create a riskless portfolio – diversification can
eliminate risk
24.00%
w E(RP) P
20.00% B
-0.5 20.0% 33.5% 16.00%
0.0 16.0 20.0

E(R)
12.00% A
0.5 12.0 6.5 8.00%

0.741 10.1 0.0 4.00%

1.0 8.0 7.0 0.00%


0.00% 10.00% 20.00% 30.00% 40.00%
1.5 4.0 20.5 Std. Dev.

17
What defines our possible portfolio choices?

 If =0, we need to carefully consider weights across


assets
24.00%
w E(RP) P 20.00%

-0.5 20.0% 30.2% 16.00%

E(R)
12.00%
0.0 16.0 20.0 8.00%

0.5 12.0 10.6 4.00%

1.0 8.0 7.0 0.00%


0.00% 10.00% 20.00% 30.00% 40.00%

1.5 4.0 14.5 Std. Dev.

 In general, 0<<1.

18
What defines our portfolio choice?
• Covariance / Correlation determines the
investment opportunity set between risky assets.
– Shape of efficient frontier between two assets is
determined by their covariance/correlation.

• Find portfolio that offers best return per unit of


risk

19
Optimal 2-Stock Portfolio

• Which portfolio combination of stocks A and B would we


want to combine with the risk-free security?

– We want the most rewarding (steepest) capital allocation line (CAL).

– Graphically: Find the tangency point between the CAL and the
efficient frontier.

– Mathematically: Maximize the Reward-to-Variability ratio over all


possible portfolio choices, subject to a few constraints.

20
Graphic Representation – where are we ?

E(R)

Rf
A


21
‘Simple’ Process for Efficient Portfolio Construction
• 1. Calculate E(R), 2, for each asset and 1,2

• 2. Find weights which maximize slope of CAL


– find portfolio P*
– calculate properties of portfolio P*

• 3. Allocate between Rf and P* to maximize your


utility (happiness).

• Let’s do this on our spreadsheet...


22
Pricing Risk

23
Investment set with N securities
• The Investment Opportunity Set is the set of all
available risk-return combinations based on portfolios
of available assets in differing proportions

E(R)

Minimum Variance
Opportunity Set

24
How many securities should we hold?
• A natural question arises:
– If we were all to make our portfolio selection by
maximizing the slope of a capital allocation line, how
many securities would we invest in?
• Answer: In a market without trading costs, we
would always add unique securities (corr ne 1),
• Unique securities allow us to “push frontier” in a
northwest direction, providing a steeper CAL.
• If each security represents a claim on a firm with at
least some unique risks (firm specific risks), we
would add all securities to our portfolio
– Everyone would hold a portfolio including each
security in the market
25
Two tasks in portfolio selection

• Two-Fund Separation: Every investor allocates wealth


between two “funds”: M and RF
– regardless of risk-aversion we would all choose the P*-weights that maximize
slope of CAL (if we all faced this same problem)
– this is the result of us all using the ‘Markowitz method’

• Portfolio selection process includes two tasks:


• Determine the optimal risky portfolio - M
– This is independent of investor preferences
• Capital Allocation between M and the risk-free asset
– Depends on individual investor’s preferences

26
Capital Asset Pricing Model

• The CAPM is a centerpiece of modern finance


that gives predictions about cross-sectional
return behavior

• CAPM begins with simplistic assumptions for


a hypothetical world of investors and builds a
reasonable & comprehensive model of
expected returns

27
Assumptions
• No taxes, transactions costs, regulations, etc. (perfectly liquid)
• Fixed quantities of infinitely divisible assets that are available
to all investors
• Trades of individual investors do not affect prices
• Unlimited short sales and borrowing and lending at Rf
• Risk-averse utility-maximizing investors who make decisions
solely on the basis of E(R) and 
– e.g., quadratic utility or normally distributed returns
• Homogeneous expectations regarding joint return distributions
– All investors ‘see’ the same E(R) and standard deviation for each
stock.
– All investors arrive at the same covariance matrix

28
Extensions from portfolio theory
• These assumptions guarantee that everyone solves the
same passive portfolio problem that we described
before
– they maximize the slope of the CAL.

• If everyone sees the same efficient frontier, then


everyone has the same tangency portfolio. So, what
must be the tangency portfolio?
– It must be the market portfolio.

29
Implication 1: Investors hold Market
Portfolio
• All investors will identify  E(RM )  R f 
same optimal risky portfolio, E ( Re )  R f    e
0.20  M 
“M” to combine with riskless
asset

Expected Return
0.15
• For supply/demand to clear,
0.10
the holdings of each security M
will be the relative market
value outstanding 0.05

0.00
• M =“Market portfolio”

0.1

0.2

0.3
0.05

0.15

0.25
Standard Deviation

30
Implication 2: Passive Indexing is Efficient

• Market portfolio is on the Capital Market


efficient frontier and it 0.20 Line
creates the best feasible E (RM )

Expected Return
0.15
capital allocation line
M
0.10
• Mutual Fund Theorem
Rational investors will 0.05
rf M
passively hold an equity
0.00
index fund & a money

0.1

0.2

0.3
0
0.05

0.15

0.25
market fund
Standard Deviation

31
Building implication 3 – EMBA skip
• Suppose that you are fully invested in RM. Consider
investing a small additional amount, , financed by
borrowing at Rf.
If we invest  in any asset i, our new portfolio E(R)
and  are:

E ( R )  E ( R M )  R f  Ri
 2   2M   2 i2  2Cov ( Ri , R M )

For small increases in  ( close to zero), the


marginal change in risk premium and variance
are:
E ( R)   [ E ( Ri )  R f ] and  2  2Cov ( Ri , R M )
32
Building implication 3 – EMBA skip
• Thus, your marginal increase in E(R) per unit of
additional risk is:
– E ( R) E ( Ri )  R f

(Eq.
 1)
2
2Cov ( Ri , R M )

• What if you instead invest  in the market portfolio?



E ( R) E ( RM )  R f E ( RM )  R f

2 (Eq. 2)

 2Cov ( R M , R M ) 2 2M

• In equilibrium, we must be indifferent between these


two choices, so: Eq. (1) = Eq. (2)
33
Implication 3: The Security Market Line
• Setting Eq. (1) equal to Eq. (2) and rearranging, we get:

Cov ( Ri , R M )
E ( Ri )  R f  2
[ E ( R M )  R f ] or
M
E(Ri )  R f  i [ E ( R M )  R f ]

• This is the CAPM or Security Market Line (SML).


• Implication: the expected risk premium on any security is
proportional to the risk premium on the market. Beta
describes the proportional relation. Beta is a measure of
priced risk.
34
Security Market Line
E ( R24%
A)
20%
SML
A
Expected Return

16% A 0
12%
8% M
4%
0%
0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5
A Beta

If a security plots off the Security Market Line, its expected


return is different from its “fair” return, or it is “mispriced.”
35
CAPM Uses (abuses)
• Value Assets and Firms
– A goal of security analysis could be to find nonzero
alpha stocks/assets

• Value Investment Choices (capital budgeting)

• Evaluate Portfolio Performance

• Benchmark for evaluating other risk factors

36
For example…

Two professional money managers are being evaluated. One


averaged 19% last year and the other managed only 16%.
However, the first manager’s beta was 1.5 and the second
manager had a beta of 1.0.

• Which manager performed better?

• If the market risk premium were 8% and T-bills were


yielding 6%, which is better?

37
Estimating Betas
• Typically, we use the regression:
Rit  ai  Bi Rmt  eit

• Estimated using historical returns on the security and the


market portfolio proxy, e.g. S&P 500

• Beta (B) is an estimate of the sensitivity of changes in


security’s return to changes in market portfolio return.

38
Estimating Beta - 2 years of weekly data
0.3
Weekly returns of MSFT
0.2
on SP500
0.1

0
-0.1 -0.05 0 0.05 0.1
-0.1

-0.2

Weekly returns of DD 0 .2
0 .1 5

on SP500 0 .1
0 .0 5
0
-0 .1 -0 .0 5 -0 .0 5 0 0 .0 5 0 .1

-0 .1
-0 .1 5
-0 .2

39
Estimating Beta
0.1
Weekly returns of 0.08
0.06
VFINX 0.04
0.02
on SP500 0
-0.1 -0.05 -0.02 0 0.05 0.1

-0.04
-0.06
-0.08

Weekly returns of 0.04


0.03
VUSTX 0.02
0.01
on SP500 0
-0.08 -0.06 -0.04 -0.02-0.01 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1
-0.02
-0.03
-0.04
-0.05

40
Beta Estimation - continued
• DD regression:
– RDD = -0.0008 + 0.8620*RSP500 R2=0.1546
» t-stat = 4.32
• MSFT regression:
– RMSFT = 0.00579 + 1.2734*RSP500 R2=0.3515
» t-stat = 7.43
• VFINX regression:
– RVFINX = -0.0002 + 0.9799*RSP500 R2=0. 9811
» t-stat = 72.95
• VUSTX regression
– RVUSTX = -0.0012 + 0.0569*RSP500 R2=0.0127
» t-stat = 1.15

41
Beta Estimates for Public Consumption
• There are many providers of ‘beta’ calculations
– Merrill Lynch Security Risk Evaluation Book or “beta book”
• Use 2nd version of market model
• market proxy = SP500 returns
• 60 monthly returns
– Value-Line
• uses 104 weekly returns and NYSE composite as a proxy for the
market to estimate betas…

• Key Point: Beta estimates can vary tremendously for a


given stock, even when you hold time-period constant.

• Back to spreadsheet to estimate stock betas


42

You might also like