Download as pptx, pdf, or txt
Download as pptx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 37

Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans model

Haile Girma (Assistant Professor)


Department of Economics
Salale University
Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans growth model
(consumption smoothening)
 In the Solow-Swan model, saving rate and,hence, the ratio of
consumption to income are exogenous and constant.
 The overall amount of investment in the economy was still
given by the saving of families, and that saving remained
exogenous.
 Not useful to study how the economy reacted to changes in
interest rates, tax rates, or other variables.
 We need a complete picture of the process of economic growth
– allow for the path of consumption and, hence, the saving rate
to be determined by optimizing households and firms that
interact on competitive markets.
 Households choose consumption and saving to maximize utility
subject to an inter-temporal budget constraint
• Names: Frank Ramsey, Tjalling Koopmans, David Cass
Key idea:
 Replace ad hoc savings [consumption] function by forward-
looking theory based utility maximization
 Specification of consumer behavior is a key element in the
Ramsey growth model, as constructed by Ramsey (1928) and
refined by Cass (1965) and Koopmans (1965).
– Hence the name Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans
 This model differs from the Solow-Swan growth model only in
one crucial respect:
– It explicitly models the consumer side and endogenizes
savings.
 In other words, it allows consumer optimization.
1. Representative consumer (RC)
Assumptions:
 Infinitely lived households;
 Identical households; each hh:
– has the same preference parameters,
– faces the same wage rate (because all workers are equally
productive),
– begins with the same assets per person, and has the same rate
of population growth.
 Use of representative-agent framework, in which the
equilibrium derives from the choices of a single household-
heterogeneity issues!
 A representative household with instantaneous utility function

 With properties:
– u(c(t)) is strictly increasing, concave, twice continuously
differentiable
– positive but diminishing marginal felicity of consumption.
 u(c) satisfies Inada conditions:

 Labour supply is exogenous and grows exponentially (with initial


labour equals 1):
and

 All members of the household supply their labor inelastically.


 Each adult supplies inelastically one unit of labor services per unit
of time.
 Households hold assets in the form of ownership claims on
capital or as loans.
– Negative loans represent debts.
 Households can lend to and borrow from other households, at
interest rate, r (t)
– but the representative household will end up holding zero net
loans in equilibrium.
 Households are competitive in that each takes as given the
interest rate, r(t), and the wage rate, w(t), paid per unit of labor
services.
 Sources of income:
– interest income plus wage income
 Use of income:
– consumption plus savings [asset accumulation]
 The household is fully altruistic towards all of its future
members, and always makes the allocations of consumption
(among household members) cooperatively.
 This implies that the objective function of each household at time
t = 0, U(0), can be written as:

Where, c(t) is consumption per capita at time t, i.e.

– Each household member will have an equal consumption


 ρ is the subjective discount rate and is assumed to be the same
across generations
– The effective discount rate is ρ−n
Notice that:
– the household will receive a utility of u(c(t)) per household
member at time t, or a total utility of

– Utility at time t is discounted back to time 0 with a discount


rate of .
 We also assume throughout that
- Ensures that in the model without growth, discounted utility is finite.
- Otherwise, the utility function would have infinite value, and standard
optimization techniques would not be useful in characterizing optimal
plans.
 A positive value of ρ (ρ>0) indicates parental “selfishness”
– Suppose that starting from a point at which the levels of
consumption per person in each generation are the same.
– Then parents prefer a unit of their own consumption to a unit of
their children’s consumption.
 No technological progress
 Factor and product markets are competitive.
 Production possibilities set of the economy:

 Standard constant returns to scale and Inada assumptions still


hold.
 Per capita production function f(.)

 Where
 Competitive factor markets imply:

 And

 Households use the income that they do not consume to


accumulate more assets
 Denote asset holdings of the representative household at time t by
A(t).
 Then,

 r(t) is the risk-free market flow rate of return on assets, and


 w(t)L(t) is the flow of labor income earnings of the household.
 Defining per capita assets as:
A t  a t   t 
A  t 
L
a t     
L t  a t  A t  L t 
 To get:

 Household assets can consist of capital stock, K(t), which they


rent to firms and government bonds, B(t).
 With uncertainty, households would have a portfolio choice
between K(t) and riskless bonds.
 With incomplete markets, bonds allow households to smooth
idiosyncratic shocks. But for now no need. Why?
– There is no government!
 Market clearing condition:
 No uncertainty and depreciation rate of δ, the market rate of
return on assets is:

The Budget Constraint


The differential equation:
Is a flow constraint.
• It is just an identity;
– hhs could accumulate debt indefinitely
• If the household can borrow unlimited amount at market interest
rate, it has an incentive to pursue a Ponzi-game.
– The household can borrow to finance current consumption and
then use future borrowings to roll over the principal and pay
all the interest.
 In this case, the household’s debt grows forever at the rate of
interest,r(t).
 To rule out chain-letter possibilities, we assume that the credit
market imposes a constraint on the amount of borrowing.
 The appropriate restriction turns out to be that the present value
of assets must be asymptotically nonnegative:

 Consider the case of borrowing by households


 Infinite-lived households tend to accumulate debt by borrowing
and never making payments for principal or interest.
 Naturally, the credit market rules out this chain-letter finance
schemes in which a household’s debt grows forever at the rate r
or higher.
– In order to borrow on this perpetual basis, households would
have to find willing lenders
– Other households that were willing to hold positive assets that
grew at the rate r or higher.
 Households will be unwilling to absorb assets asymptotically at
such a high rate.
– It would be suboptimal for households to accumulate positive
assets forever at the rate r or higher,
– because utility would increase if these assets were instead
consumed in finite time.
 Household maximization
• Set up the current value of Hamiltonian function

• with state variable a, control variable c and current-value costate


variable μ.
• It represents the value of an increment of income received at time
t in units of utils at time 0.
• FOCs:
(i)
(ii)

Ĥ
 t       t   r t   n 
a t 
• The transversality condition is:

• What is transversality condition?


– The transversality condition for an infinite horizon dynamic
optimization problem is the boundary condition determining a
solution to the problem's first-order conditions together with the
initial condition.
– The transversality condition requires the present value of the
state variables to converge to zero as the planning horizon
recedes towards infinity
• Intuition:
• The transversality condition ensures that the individual would
never want to ‘die’ with positive wealth.
– An optimizing agents do not want to have any valuable assets
left over at the end.
• From (ii), we obtain,

• The multiplier changes depending on whether the rate of return


on assets is currently greater than or less than the discount rate of
the household.
• The first necessary condition above implies that
The Euler Equation
• Differentiate equation (i) with respect to time and divide by), ,
we get the basic condition for choosing consumption over time:

• Upon substitution into (ii), we get the famous consumer Euler


equation:

• Where

• is the elasticity of the marginal utility u’(c(t)).


• Consumption will grow over time when the discount rate is less
than the rate of return on assets.
• It also specifies the speed at which consumption will grow in
response to a gap between this rate of return and the discount rate.
• Elasticity of marginal utility is the inverse of the intertemporal
elasticity of substitution.
• The elasticity between the dates t and s > t is defined as:

• As s approaches t, we get:
Equilibrium Prices
• The market rate of return for consumers, r (t), is given by:

• Substituting this into the consumer’s problem, we have:

• It is simply the equilibrium version of the consumption growth


equation.
Optimal Growth
• Capital and consumption path chosen by a benevolent social
planner trying to achieve a Pareto optimal outcome.
• The optimal growth problem simply involves the maximization of
the utility of the representative household subject to technology
and feasibility constraints.

• Subject to

• and k (0) > 0.


• Set up the current-value Hamiltonian:

• With state variable k, control variable c and current-value costate


variable μ.
• The necessary conditions for an optimal path are:
• It is straightforward to see that these optimality conditions imply:

• The transversality condition

• Both are identical with the previous results


– This establishes that the competitive equilibrium is a Pareto
optimum
– The equilibrium is Pareto optimal and coincides with the
optimal growth path maximizing the utility of the
representative household.
Steady-State Equilibrium
• Characterize the steady-state equilibrium and optimal allocations
• A steady state equilibrium is an equilibrium path in which capital-
labor ratio, consumption and output are constant.

• Since f(k∗) > 0, we must have a capital-labor ratio k∗ such that:

• The steady-state capital-labor ratio only as a function of the


production function, the discount rate and the depreciation rate.
• This corresponds to the modified golden rule:
• The interest rate equals:
f '  k t       rKR
 
• The modified golden rule involves a level of the capital stock that
does not maximize steady-state consumption
– This is due to discounting (i.e. earlier consumption is preferred
to later consumption).
– The objective is not to maximize steady state consumption
rather giving higher weight to earlier consumption
• Given k∗, the steady-state consumption level is:

• Which is similar to the consumption level in the basic Solow


model.
Transitional Dynamics
• Unlike the Solow-Swan model, equilibrium is determined by two
differential equations:

• Moreover, we have an initial condition k(0) > 0, also a boundary


condition at infinity:

• The intersection of and define the steady state (next


slide).
• The former is vertical since a unique level of k* can keep per
consumption constant ( ).
Dynamics of c
• since all households are the same, the evolution of C for the entire
economy is:

• There are two ways for to be zero:


(i) c(t)=0; corresponds to the horizontal axis
(ii) f '  k t      which
0 is a vertical line at k*.
• Ignore the first case, and focus on the second.
f '  k t      
• This provide the optimal level of k, denoted by k*
• When k exceeds k*, f '  k t       c  0

• The opposite holds when k is less than k*.


• This is summarized in Figure 1 (next slide)
• c is rising if k<k* and declining if k>k*.

• The c  0 occurs at k=k* and c is constant for this value of k.


Figure 1: Dynamics of c
Dynamics of k
• The dynamics of the economy is given by:

• Notice that k t   0 implies that


c  t   f  k t     n    k t 
• Consumption equals the difference between actual output and
break-even investment.
• c is increasing in k until dc t   0 
dk  t 
f '  k  t    n    r t   n  
• The last expression gives the golden rule of capital per worker (k*)
• When exceeds that yields  , k is decreasing, and vice versa .
k t 0 
Figure 2: Dynamics of k
When k is large and break-even investment exceeds total output, k t   0
for all positive values of c.
• The dynamics of c and k: bringing the two together
• The arrows show direction of motion of c and k
• Consider the following: points to the left of c t   0 and above k t   0
• The former is positive the latter is negative
• c is rising while k is falling
• On the c t   k t   0 curves, only one of c and k is changing.
• Example: on the c t   0 line and above k t   0 locus, c is constant
and k is falling.
• At point E when c t   k t   0 holds, there is no movement.
Figure 3: Dynamics of c and k
• The economy can converge to this steady state if it starts in two
of the four quadrants in which the two schedules divide the
space.
• Given this direction of movements, it is clear that there exists a
unique stable arm, the one-dimensional manifold tending to the
steady state.
• All points away from this stable arm diverge, and eventually
reach zero consumption or zero capital stock
• Consider the following:
• If initial consumption, c(0), started above this stable arm, say at
c’(0), the capital stock would reach 0 in finite time, while
consumption would remain positive.
• But this would violate feasibility.
– Therefore, initial values of consumption above this stable
arm cannot be part of the equilibrium
• If the initial level of consumption were below it, for example, at
c’’(0), consumption would reach zero.
• Thus capital would accumulate continuously until the maximum level
of capital (reached with zero consumption)
Continuous capital accumulation towards with no consumption
would violate the transversality condition.
• There exists a unique equilibrium path starting from any k(0)>0 and
converging to the unique steady-state (k∗, c∗) with k∗.

You might also like