Download as pptx, pdf, or txt
Download as pptx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 33

BEC 30325

Managerial Economics

Managerial Decisions for Firms


with Market Power
Market Power
• Ability of a firm to raise price without losing all
its sales
– Any firm that faces downward sloping demand has
market power
• Gives firm ability to raise price above average
cost & earn economic profit (if demand & cost
conditions permit)
Monopoly
• Single firm
• Produces & sells a good or service for which
there are no close substitutes
• New firms are prevented from entering
market because of a barrier to entry
Measurement of Market Power
• Degree of market power inversely related to price
elasticity of demand
– The less elastic the firm’s demand, the greater its
degree of market power
– The fewer close substitutes for a firm’s product, the
smaller the elasticity of demand (in absolute value) &
the greater the firm’s market power
– When demand is perfectly elastic (demand is
horizontal), the firm has no market power
Measurement of Market Power
• Lerner index measures proportionate amount by
which price exceeds marginal cost:
– Equals zero under perfect competition
– Increases as market power increases
– Also equals –1/E, which shows that the index (& market power), vary
inversely with elasticity
– The lower the elasticity of demand (absolute value), the greater the
index & the degree of market power

P  MC
Lerner index 
P
Measurement of Market Power
• If consumers view two goods as substitutes,
cross-price elasticity of demand (EXY) is
positive
– The higher the positive cross-price elasticity, the
greater the substitutability between two goods, &
the smaller the degree of market power for the
two firms
Barriers to Entry
• Entry of new firms into a market erodes
market power of existing firms by increasing
the number of substitutes
• A firm can possess a high degree of market
power only when strong barriers to entry exist
– Conditions that make it difficult for new firms to
enter a market in which economic profits are
being earned
Common Entry Barriers
• Economies of scale
– When long-run average cost declines over a wide
range of output relative to demand for the
product, there may not be room for another large
producer to enter market
• Barriers created by government
– Licenses, exclusive franchises
Common Entry Barriers
• Essential input barriers
– One firm controls a crucial input in the production
process
• Brand loyalties
– Strong customer allegiance to existing firms may
keep new firms from finding enough buyers to
make entry worthwhile
Common Entry Barriers
• Consumer lock-in
– Potential entrants can be deterred if they believe
high switching costs will keep them from inducing
many consumers to change brands
• Network externalities
– Occur when benefit or utility of a product
increases as more consumers buy & use it
– Make it difficult for new firms to enter markets
where firms have established a large base or
network of buyers
Demand & Marginal Revenue for a Monopolist

• Market demand curve is the firm’s demand curve


• Monopolist must lower price to sell additional
units of output
– Marginal revenue is less than price for all but the first
unit sold
• When MR is positive (negative), demand is elastic
(inelastic)
• For linear demand, MR is also linear, has the same
vertical intercept as demand, & is twice as steep
Demand & Marginal Revenue for a Monopolist
Short-Run Profit Maximization for Monopoly

• Monopolist will produce where MR = SMC as long


as TR at least covers the firm’s total avoidable cost
(TR ≥ TVC)
– Price for this output is given by the demand curve
• If TR < TVC (or, equivalently, P < AVC) the firm
shuts down & loses only fixed costs
• If P > ATC, firm makes economic profit
• If ATC > P > AVC, firm incurs a loss, but continues to
produce in short run
Short-Run Profit Maximization for Monopoly
Short-Run Loss Minimization for Monopoly
Long-Run Profit Maximization for Monopoly

• Monopolist maximizes profit by choosing to


produce output where MR = LMC, as long as
P  LAC
• Will exit industry if P < LAC
• Monopolist will adjust plant size to the
optimal level
– Optimal plant is where the short-run average cost
curve is tangent to the long-run average cost at
the profit-maximizing output level
Long-Run Profit Maximization for Monopoly
Profit-Maximizing Input Usage
• Profit-maximizing level of input usage
produces exactly that level of output that
maximizes profit
Profit-Maximizing Input Usage
• Marginal revenue product (MRP)
– MRP is the additional revenue attributable to hiring
one more unit of the input
TR
MRP   MR  MP
L
• When producing with a single variable
input:
• Employ amount of input for which MRP = input price
• Relevant range of MRP curve is downward sloping, positive portion,
for which ARP > MRP
Monopoly Firm’s Demand for Labor
Profit-Maximizing Input Usage
• For a firm with market power, profit-
maximizing conditions MRP = w and MR
= MC are equivalent
– Whether Q or L is chosen to maximize profit,
resulting levels of input usage, output, price, &
profit are the same
Monopolistic Competition
• Large number of firms sell a differentiated
product
– Products are close (not perfect) substitutes
• Market is monopolistic
– Product differentiation creates a degree of
market power
• Market is competitive
– Large number of firms, easy entry
Monopolistic Competition
• Short-run equilibrium is identical to
monopoly
• Unrestricted entry/exit leads to long-run
equilibrium
– Attained when demand curve for each producer
is tangent to LAC
– At equilibrium output, P = LAC and
MR = LMC
Short-Run Profit Maximization for Monopolistic Competition
Long-Run Profit Maximization for Monopolistic Competition
Implementing the Profit-Maximizing Output & Pricing Decision

• Step 1: Estimate demand equation


– Use statistical techniques from Chapter 7
– Substitute forecasts of demand-shifting
variables into estimated demand equation to
get

Q = a′ + bP
ˆ  dPˆ
Where a'  a  cM R
Implementing the Profit-Maximizing Output & Pricing Decision

• Step 2: Find inverse demand equation


– Solve for P

 a' 1
P  Q  A  BQ
b b
ˆ ˆ  a' 1
Where a'  a  cM  dPR , A  , and B 
b b
Implementing the Profit-Maximizing Output & Pricing Decision

• Step 3: Solve for marginal revenue


– When demand is expressed as P = A + BQ, marginal
revenue is
 a' 2
MR  A  2 BQ   Q
b b

• Step 4: Estimate AVC & SMC


• Use statistical techniques from Chapter 10
AVC = a + bQ + cQ2
SMC = a + 2bQ + 3cQ2
Implementing the Profit-Maximizing Output & Pricing Decision

• Step 5: Find output where MR = SMC


– Set equations equal & solve for Q*
– The larger of the two solutions is the profit-
maximizing output level
• Step 6: Find profit-maximizing price
– Substitute Q* into inverse demand
P* = A + BQ*

Q* & P* are only optimal if P  AVC


Implementing the Profit-Maximizing Output & Pricing Decision

• Step 7: Check shutdown rule


– Substitute Q* into estimated AVC function

AVC* = a + bQ* + cQ*2

• If P*  AVC*, produce Q* units of output & sell


each unit for P*
• If P* < AVC*, shut down in short run
Implementing the Profit-Maximizing Output & Pricing Decision

• Step 8: Compute profit or loss


– Profit = TR – TC
= P x Q* - AVC x Q* - TFC
= (P – AVC)Q* - TFC

– If P < AVC, firm shuts down & profit is -TFC


Multiple Plants
• If a firm produces in 2 plants, A & B
– Allocate production so MCA = MCB
– Optimal total output is that for which MR = MCT
• For profit-maximization, allocate total output
so that
MR = MCT = MCA = MCB
A Multiplant Firm

You might also like