Download as ppt, pdf, or txt
Download as ppt, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 28

CHAPTER 8

Economic Growth II: Technology,


Empirics and Policy

A PowerPointTutorial
To Accompany

MACROECONOMICS, 7th. Edition


N. Gregory Mankiw
Tutorial written by:
Mannig J. Simidian
Chapter Eight B.A. in Economics with Distinction, Duke University 1
M.P.A., Harvard University Kennedy School of Government
M.B.A., Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT) Sloan School of Management
The
TheSolow
Solowmodel
modeldoes
doesnot
notexplain
explaintechnological
technologicalprogress
progressbut,
but,
instead,
instead,takes
takesititas
asgiven
givenand
andshows
showshow
howititinteracts
interactswith
withother
other
variables
variablesininthe
theprocess
processofofeconomic
economicgrowth.
growth.

Chapter Eight 2
To examine how a nation’s public policies can influence the level
and growth of the citizens’ standard of living, we must ask five
questions.

1) Should our society save more or less?


2) How can policy influence the rate of saving?
3) Are there some types of investment that policy should encourage?
4) What institutions ensure that the economy’s resources are put
to their best use?
5) How can policy increase the rate of technological progress?
The Solow model provides the theoretical framework within which
we consider these issues.
Chapter Eight 3
To incorporate technological progress,
the Production Function is now written as:
Y = F (K, L  E)

The term L  E measures the number of workers.


This takes into account the number of workers L and the efficiency
of each worker, E. It states that total output Y depends on capital K
and workers L  E. The essence of this model is that increases in E
(efficiency) are analogous to increases in L (number of workers). In
other words, a single worker (if twice as productive)
can be thought of as two workers. L  E doubles and the economy
benefits from the increased production of goods and services.
Chapter Eight 4
Technological
Technologicalprogress
progresscauses
causesEEtotogrow
growatatthe
therate
rateg,g,and
andLLgrows
grows
atatrate
ratennso
sothe
thenumber
numberof workersLLEEisisgrowing
ofworkers growingatatrate
ratenn++g.g.
Now,
Now,the thechange
changein inthe
thecapital
capitalstock
stockper
perworker
workeris:is:
kk==ii–(
–(
nng)k,
g)k,where
whereiiisisequal
equalto
tossf(k).
f(k).

sf(k) n + g)k


The Steady State Note:
Note:kk==K/LE
K/LEand y=Y/(L
andy=Y/(L 
So,
So,yy==f(k)
f(k)isisnow
nowdifferent.
different.
Investment,
sf(k) Also,
Also,when
whenthe
theggterm
termisisadded,
added,
gk
gkisisneeded
neededtotoprovided
providedcapital
capital
to
tonew
new“effective
“effectiveworkers”
workers”
created
createdbybytechnological
technologicalprogress.
progress.
Chapter Eight
k* Capital 5
per worker, k
Important…
Labor-augmenting technological progress at rate g affects the Solow
growth model in much the same way as did population growth at rate
n. Now that k is defined as the amount of capital per effective worker,
increases in the number of effective workers because of technological
progress tend to decrease k. In the steady state, investment sf(k)
exactly offsets the reductions in k because of depreciation, population
growth, and technological progress.

Chapter Eight 6
Capital
Capitalper
pereffective
effectiveworker
workerisisconstant
constantin
inthe
thesteady
steadystate.
state.
Because
Becauseyy==f(k),
f(k),output
outputper
pereffective
effectiveworker
workerisisalso
alsoconstant.
constant.But
But
the
theefficiency
efficiencyofofeach
eachactual
actualworker
workerisisgrowing
growingatatrate
rate g.g.So,
So,
output
outputper
perworker, (Y/L==yyE)
worker,(Y/L E)also
alsogrows
growsatatrate
rateg.g.Total
Totaloutput
output
YY==yy(E(EL)
L)grows
growsatatrate
ratenn++g.g.

Chapter Eight 7
The introduction of technological progress also modifies the
criterion for the Golden Rule. The Golden Rule level of capital is
now defined as the steady state that maximizes consumption per
effective worker. So, we can show that steady-state consumption
per effective worker is:
c*= (k*)--((
c*=ff(k*) nn++ggk*
k*

Steady-state consumption is maximized if


MPK = n + g,
rearranging, MPK - n + g.
That is, at the Golden Rule level of capital, the net marginal
product of capital, MPK - equals the rate of growth of total
output, n + g. Because actual economies experience both
population growth and technological progress, we must use this
criterion to evaluate whether they have more or less capital than
they would at the Golden Rule steady state.
Chapter Eight 8
Capital per effective worker k = K/(E L) 0
Output per effective worker y = Y/ (E  L) = f(k) 0
Output per worker Y/L = y g
Total output Y = y L) n+g

Chapter Eight 9
So far we have introduced technological progress into the
Solow model to explain sustained growth in standards of living.
Let’s now discuss what happens when theory meets facts.

Chapter Eight 10
According to the Solow model, technological progress causes
the values of many variables to rise together in the steady state
This property is called balanced growth.

In the steady state, output per worker, Y/L, and capital stock per
worker, K/L, both grow at rate g, which is the rate of technological
progress. This is consistent with U.S. data in that g has been
about 2 percent consistently over the past 50 years.

Technological progress also affects factor prices. The real wage


grows at the rate of technological progress, but the real rental
price of capital remains constant over time. Again, over the last
50 years, the real wage has increased by 2 percent and has increased by
about the same as real GDP. Yet, the real rental price of capital (real
capital income divided by the capital stock) has been about the same.
Chapter Eight 11
The property of catch-up is called convergence. If there
is not convergence, countries that start off poor are
likely to remain poor.
The Solow model makes predictions about when
convergence should occur. According to the model,
whether two economies will converge depends on why
they differ in the first place (i.e., savings rates,
population growth rates, and human capital accumulation).

Chapter Eight 12
Differences in income are a result of either:

1) Factors of production such as the quantities of physical and human


capital
2) Efficiency with which economies use their factors of production

Put simply, workers in a poor country either don’t have the tools
and skills, or they are not putting their tools and skills to the best use.

Chapter Eight 13
In terms of the Solow model, the central question is whether
the large gap between the rich and poor is explained by
differences in capital accumulation, or differences in the
production function.

Chapter Eight 14
The savings rate determines the steady-state levels of capital and
output. One particular saving rate produces the Golden Rule steady
state, which maximizes consumption per worker. Let’s use the
Golden Rule to analyze the U.S. saving rate.

Marginal product of capital Growth rate of total output


net of depreciation (n + g)
(MPK – )

Recall that at the Golden Rule steady state, (MPK – ) = (n + g)

Chapter Eight 15
If the economy is operating
with more capital than in the
Golden Rule steady state,
then (MPK –  < n + g)

Amount of capital in the Golden Rule steady state

If the economy is operating


with less capital than in the
Golden Rule steady state,
then (MPK –  > n + g)

Chapter Eight 16
Marginal
Marginalproduct
productof
ofcapital
capital Growth
Growthrate
rateof
oftotal
totaloutput
output
net
netof
ofdepreciation
depreciation (n
(n++g)
g)
(MPK––))
(MPK

To make this comparison for the U.S. economy, we need to estimate


the growth rate of output (n + g) and an estimate of the net marginal
product of capital (MPK – ). U.S. GDP grows at about 3 percent per
year, so, n + g = 0.03. We can estimate the net marginal product of
capital from the following facts:

Chapter Eight 17
1) The capital stock is about 2.5 times one year’s GDP, or k = 2.5y
2) Depreciation of capital is about 10 percent of GDP, or dk = 0.1y
3) Capital income is about 30 percent of GDP, or MPK  k = 0.3y

We solve for the rate of depreciation  by


dividing equation 2 by equation 1:
k/k = (0.1y)/(2.5y)
 = 0.04
And we solve for the marginal product of capital (MPK)
by dividing equation 3 by equation 1:
(MPK k)/k = (0.3y)/(2.5y)
MPK = 0.12
Thus, about 4 percent of the capital stock depreciates each year, and
the marginal product of capital is about 12 percent per year. The net
marginal product of capital, MPK – d, is about 8 percent per year.
Chapter Eight 18
We can now see that the returns to capital (MPK –  = 8 percent per
year) is well in excess of the economy’s growth rate (n + g = 3 percent
per year).

This indicates that the capital stock in the U.S. economy is well
below the Golden Rule-level. In other words, if the United States saved
and invested a higher fraction of its income, it would grow faster and
eventually reach a steady state with higher consumption.

Chapter Eight 19
Public saving is the difference between what the government receives
in tax revenue minus what it spends.

When spending > revenue, it is a budget deficit


When spending < revenue, it is a budget surplus 

Private saving is the saving done by households and firms.

Chapter Eight 20
• In 2009, one of President Barack Obama’s
first economic proposals was to increase
spending on public infrastructure such as
new roads, bridges, and transit systems.
• This policy was partly motivated by a desire
to increase short-run aggregate demand and
partly to provide public capital and enhance
long-run economic growth.

Chapter Eight 21
Nations may have different levels of productivity in part because
they have different institutions that govern the allocation of their
scarce resources.

For example, a nation’s legal tradition is an institution. Other


examples are the quality of the government itself and the level of
corruption that exists within the political infrastructure.

Chapter Eight 22
The Solow model shows that sustained growth in income per worker
must come from technological progress. The Solow model, however,
takes technological progress as exogenous, and therefore does not
explain it.

Chapter Eight 23
?

The Endogenous Growth Theory rejects


Solow’s basic assumption of exogenous technological change.

Chapter Eight 24
Start with a simple production function: Y = AK, where Y is output,
K is the capital stock, and A is a constant measuring the amount of
output produced for each unit of capital (noticing this production
function does not have diminishing returns to capital). One extra unit
of capital produces A extra units of output regardless of how much
capital there is. This absence of diminishing returns to capital is
the key difference between this endogenous growth model and the
Solow model.

Let’s describe capital accumulation with an equation similar to those


we’ve been using: K = sY - K. This equation states that the change
in the capital stock (K) equals investment (sY) minus depreciation
(K). We combine this equation with the production function, do
some rearranging, and we get: Y/Y = K/K = sA – 
Chapter Eight 25
Y/Y = K/K = sA - 

This equation shows what determines the growth rate of output Y/Y.
Notice that as long as sA > , the economy’s income grows forever,
even without the assumption of exogenous technological progress.

In the Solow model, saving leads to growth temporarily, but diminishing


returns to capital eventually force the economy to approach a steady
state in which growth depends only on exogenous technological progress.

By contrast, in this endogenous growth model, saving and investment can


lead to persistent growth.

Chapter Eight 26
Creative Destruction

Schumpeter suggested that the economy’s progress come through


a process a creative destruction. According to Schumpeter, the
driving force behind progress is the entrepreneur with an idea
for a new product, a new way to produce an old product, or
some other innovation.
Chapter Eight 27
Efficiency
Efficiencyof
oflabor
labor
Labor-augmenting
Labor-augmentingtechnological
technologicalprogress
progress
Endogenous
Endogenousgrowth
growththeory
theory

Chapter Eight 28

You might also like